National Post

Populists base their agendas on untrue narrative

- David Brooks

Mi ddle- class wage stagnation is the biggest economic fact driving American politics. Over the past many years, so the common argument goes, capitalism has developed structural flaws. Economic gains are not being shared fairly with the middle class. Wages have become decoupled f rom productivi­ty. Even when the economy grows, everything goes to the rich.

This account of reality, which I’ve certainly repeated, explains why the Democratic Party has moved from the Bill Clinton neoliberal centre to the Bernie Sanders left. It explains why the Republican­s have moved from the pro-market Mitt Romney right to the populist Donald Trump right.

On both left and right, movements have arisen to fix capitalism’s supposed structural flaws, either by radically interferin­g in the marketplac­e ( Bernie) or by clamping down on global competitio­n ( Trump).

But what if there are no structural flaws? What if the market is working more or less as it’s supposed to?

That’s certainly the evidence in the U. S. from the last two years. Over this time, the benefits of economic growth have been shared more widely.

In 2015, median U. S. household incomes rose by 5.2 per cent. That was the fastest surge in percentage terms since the U. S. Census Bureau began keeping records in the 1960s. Women living alone saw their incomes rise by 8.7 per cent. Median incomes for American Hispanics rose by 6.1 per cent. Immigrants’ incomes, excluding naturalize­d citizens, jumped by over 10 per cent.

The news was especially good for the poor. The share of overall income that went to the poorest fifth increased by three per cent, while the share that went to the affluent groups did not change. In that year, the poverty rate fell by 1.2 percentage points, the steepest decline since 1999.

The numbers for 2016 have just been released by the U. S. Census Bureau, and the trends are pretty much the same. Median U. S. household income rose another 3.2 per cent, after inflation, to its highest level ever. The poverty rate fell some more. The share of national income going to labour is now rising, while the share going to capital is falling.

In a well- f unc t i oning economy, workers are rewarded for their productivi­ty. As output, jobs and hours worked rise, so does income. Over the past two years, that seems to be exactly what’s happening.

The evidence from the past two years strongly supports those who have argued all along that income has not decoupled from productivi­ty. A wide range of economists, including Martin Feldstein, Stephen Rose, Edward Lazear, Joao Paulo Pessoa, John Van Reenen, Richard Anderson of the St. Louis Fed, and a team from Goldman Sachs, have produced studies showing wages tracking very predictabl­y with productivi­ty.

If anything, wages are a little higher than you’d expect from looking at the productivi­ty and inflation numbers alone.

The problem of the American middle-class squeeze, in short, may not be with how the fruits of productivi­ty are distribute­d, but the fact that there isn’t much productivi­ty growth at all. It’s not that a rising tide doesn’t lift all boats; it’s that the tide is not rising fast enough.

For those interested, Shawn Sprague has a good summary of the data at the U.S. Lab or Department’ s “Beyond the Numbers.” He shows conclusive­ly t hat during this recovery we’ve endured a historical­ly low labour productivi­ty growth rate of 1.1 per cent. By some estimates, if productivi­ty increases had kept pace with the mid-20th-century norm, median incomes would be US$40,000 higher than they are today.

If productivi­ty itself is the problem, not distributi­on, radically different politics is demanded than we’re seeing today. If productivi­ty is the problem, we need more dynamism, not less, more openness, not less, more growth- oriented policies, not more dirigiste and redistribu­tive ones.

There are a few things government can do to help boost productivi­ty: Increase market competitio­n with more antitrust enforcemen­t and fewer licensing regulation­s; admit more skilled immigrants; invest more in human capital; deregulate urban land usage back to the 2008 levels; introduce more market incentives into the low productivi­ty sectors, like health care and education; fund more research into promising technologi­es like new energy storage systems.

Today politics is polarizing to the populist left and the populist right. But if productivi­ty is the problem, what we actually need is a resurgence of the moderates. The moderate- left policies of Barack Obama must have had something to do with the middle- income gains of the last two years. Moderate Democrats can plausibly argue that government should not be interferin­g in the markets, but it should be addressing the inequaliti­es that are the result of deeper social forces. There is still a yawning gap dividing the median Asian- American household, which makes US$81,000 a year; the median white household, which makes US$ 65,000; and the median African- American household, which makes US$39,490.

Moderate Republican­s can argue that while government should be active in boosting human capital, and in helping rural America, most of what’s needed is more dynamic capitalism — more trade, more immigratio­n, more free competitio­n, fewer regulatory burdens, more growth.

Right now moderates are in retreat. The populist extremes are on the march. But the fact is they are basing their economic and political agendas on a story that is fundamenta­lly untrue.

WHAT IF THE MARKET IS WORKING MORE OR LESS AS IT’S SUPPOSED TO?

MANY REPORT FEELING LIKE ODDBALLS. — ARTHUR C. BROOKS

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada