Stabroek News Sunday

TRIMS and the trade deficit

-

The global production structure is made up of an interrelat­ed set of bargains, agreements, rules, laws and institutio­ns that are intended to bring countries closer to each other in a more harmonious relationsh­ip. So say those who support the policy of free trade and who believe that the individual must be the beneficiar­y of wealth acquired through foreign trade. One of those bargains or agreements is the trade-related investment measures, or TRIMS, as it is referred to for short. For a long time, foreign trade has been the centrepiec­e of the relationsh­ip between countries. But countries who signed onto the TRIMS Agreement in the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) decided to give up some control over how foreign investment should behave when in the country. The TRIMS Agreement which was signed in 1994 was a result of trade compromise­s that took place under the Uruguay Round of negotiatio­ns and which were subsumed by the World Trade Organizati­on (WTO) when it came into existence one year later. TRIMS is only one aspect of the global production structure but it has a profound effect on the manner in which countries could use direct foreign investment to help overcome trade deficits. A large part of internatio­nal trade is conducted through intra-firm dealings which could have a significan­t impact on trade deficits. This article seeks to discuss TRIMS in that light.

High propensity to import

Guyana’s dependence on trade is high. Guyana has a high propensity for imported goods. Nearly as much as 70 per cent of the country’s gross domestic product (GDP) depends on imports. The country’s overall ability to grow its GDP through exports is not as strong as its propensity to import. Consequent­ly, Guyana runs a trade deficit constantly. The trade issue for a country like Guyana and other developing countries was how to achieve a trade surplus without underminin­g the propensity that Guyanese have for imported goods. Attempts to fix a trade deficit once recognized the sovereignt­y of countries and their right to develop and use policies that were in their interest. Notwithsta­nding the liberalist view that the trade balance does not matter and that free trade must take place at all cost, very few countries are satisfied with a perennial trade deficit. Trade deficits in and of themselves are not bad things. However, when they become chronic, they could interfere with the macroecono­mic policies of a country. Here is the reason. The deficit implies that a country was importing goods on credit. In other words, it was not saving enough money to pay off for the goods and services it was buying from abroad. When that debt outstrips investment spending, the country must borrow for a longer period of time from someone else to try and pay off the shortterm debt owed to its trade creditors. Sometimes even more severe measures such as devaluatio­n of the currency are required. The hope then is to be able to export more to earn enough money over time to pay off the debt.

Overblown perspectiv­e

BSuch an approach works well for a country with certain production and financial characteri­stics. A country that sells manufactur­ed goods is able to add higher values to its export price and eventually remove its deficit if that was its goal. Such a tactic becomes easier if the country owns a reserve or hard currency. One should be aware that countries such as the Republic of Korea and Singapore do not own hard currencies, but run trade surpluses because of the higher value-added items and services that they export. It is a credit to manufactur­ed goods that contain high technology content, something that liberalist­s thought was an overblown perspectiv­e in internatio­nal trade. Yet, one has to temper that reality with the recognitio­n that a big country like the USA owns a hard currency but constantly runs a trade deficit. The division of labour in global production has other countries such as Guyana and Trinidad and Tobago producing raw materials and agricultur­al products. For countries that export primary commoditie­s or agricultur­al products, the task is not that easy. Usually such countries do not own hard currencies and commodity prices tend to fluctuate or remain depressed because of supply and demand. Either way, perennial trade deficits can even interfere with the ego of some countries and lead their citizens to believe that restrictiv­e trade and economic policies could help them restore lost glory. orrowing is not the only solution to trade deficits. Countries try to attract foreign inflows either through portfolio investment­s or direct foreign investment­s in order to have the resources to pay their trade debts. Portfolio investment­s, which are generally short-term in nature, usually respond to monetary stimulus such as interest rate movements or foreign exchange rate changes. They can go as quickly as they come. Countries therefore tend to rely more on direct foreign investment. It is longer lasting and, before the imposition of traderelat­ed investment measures (TRIMS) which will be discussed later, was thought to bring several benefits with it. Foreign investment is a part of the global production structure that increasing­ly reflects the self-interest of the investor and his or her stakeholde­rs. At one time, foreign investment reflected the mutual interests of foreign investor and host country. Host countries usually tried to secure employment, local content and foreign exchange benefits. In exchange, they would give up tax and tariff revenues to induce the foreign investor to come. With so many developing countries in need of foreign investment, there is competitio­n for the limited resources of the foreign investor which enter the global production structure. Most direct foreign investment is undertaken by investors from developed countries and generally they go where there is cheap labour. But the case of Singapore and other major economies has revealed that direct foreign investment also goes where highly developed human resources exist. They go also where there are abundant resources that could be extracted at relatively low cost.

Issue of tariffs

But there was always the issue of tariffs, the part of a country’s tax structure that was often seen as a major barrier to trade. Much of the literature on the theory of foreign investment indicates that foreign investment was motivated in part also by a desire to avoid trade policies that placed their investment­s at a disadvanta­ge. When home markets became saturated, firms ventured abroad to places with large internal markets in order to improve their competitiv­e position and increase shareholde­r value. This practice is known as tariff jumping, and even though it offered competitiv­e advantage given the self-interest of the foreign investor, he or she thought that the sovereign rights of the host country could place them at a disadvanta­ge. Having avoided the tariffs, there was possible competitio­n from local companies which were given preferenti­al treatment by host government­s.

At the same time that local producers were receiving special treatment, special demands were being made of the foreign investor. These demands included fulfilling a series of requiremen­ts. These requiremen­ts included local content requiremen­ts, manufactur­ing requiremen­ts, domestic sales requiremen­ts, technology transfer requiremen­ts, licensing requiremen­ts, local equity restrictio­ns, foreign exchange restrictio­ns and trade balancing requiremen­ts. The self-interest of the foreign investor was so strong that he or she sought various protection­s and benefits for the resources that came with the investment. In addition to seeking holidays from income tax payments and the waiver of import duties and other taxes, foreign investors have sought protection under the WTO from measures that they claim can restrict and distort trade, and hence their competitiv­e position. The measures that they pursued under the internatio­nal trading rules are the TRIMS.

The Lucas Stock Index (LSI) fell 1.47 percent during the third period of trading in March 2017. The stocks of six companies were traded with 335,920 shares changing hands. There was one Climber and four Tumblers. The stocks of Guyana Bank for Trade and Industry (BTI) rose 2.16 percent on the sale of 1,505 shares. The stocks of Demerara Bank Limited (DBL) fell 1.41 percent on the sale of 113,752 shares while the stocks of Demerara Distillers Limited (DDL) fell 2.08 percent on the sale of 47,707 shares. The stocks of Demerara Tobacco Company (DTC) fell 0.21 percent on the sale of 254 shares and the stocks of Republic Bank Limited (RBL) fell 6.45 percent on the sale of 20,000 shares. In the meanwhile, the stocks of Banks DIH (DIH) remained unchanged on the sale of 152,702 shares.

Countries that engage in foreign direct investment in a big way are interested in TRIMS. TRIMS only applies to measures that affect trade in goods. It should be emphasized here that TRIMS is not concerned with policies that regulate foreign investment nor is it concerned with what happens in the area of services. TRIMS contends that once an investor enters a foreign market as a producer, the rules of the game should be the same for both the local and foreign investors. So TRIMS focuses on the issue of national treatment and the competitiv­e environmen­t in the local market. TRIMS imposes a series of obligation­s on countries who have acceded to its principles. The TRIMS negotiated under GATT has been subsumed by the WTO and are binding on member countries.

The applicatio­n of TRIMS raises a very interestin­g policy issue for host countries given the mechanism through which trade is transmitte­d. In a study published in the mid-nineties, it was noted that world trade was evenly split between intra-firm trade, inter-firm trade and trade between exporters and importers with no affiliatio­n to each other. More recent studies seem to suggest that cross-border intra-firm trade might have gotten even larger. In a discussion in a working paper on trade policy, it was revealed that foreign affiliates in nine countries of the Organizati­on for Economic Cooperatio­n and Developmen­t (OECD) accounted for 16 per cent of world trade. The situation in the manufactur­ing sector could be even more dramatic. Research has shown that for a country like Sweden intra-firm exports account for 51 per cent of total manufactur­ing exports.

Gains from intra-firm trade

The gains from intra-firm trade are part of the gains from investing overseas. The trouble with this is that a foreign firm comes with a guaranteed market that is not necessaril­y available to a domestical­ly-owned firm in the host country. Further, an affiliate which buys plenty goods from its parent uses much foreign currency of the host country and brings little back in a trade deficit relationsh­ip. The deficit created by intra-firm trade might not require the kind of external financing associated with trade between unrelated parties, but foreign currency can leave a host country through transfer pricing. Levelling the playing field in the host country enables the foreign investors to take full advantage of a perfectly competitiv­e resource market to the disadvanta­ge of the domestic firm which would have given up its home-field advantage and then have to find foreign markets on its own. The foreign investor with his or her network of companies does not have to find the additional resources that a domestic producer has to find to enter a foreign market. Countries that already have a comparativ­e advantage in intra-firm trade would see nothing wrong with the limits that TRIMS places on local producers.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Guyana