Houston Chronicle

Do markets work in health care delivery?

David Brooks says that there’s psychology as well as economics in a system based on consumers.

-

Believe it or not, we’re not really going to have to spend the next four years wading through wonky drudgery of Russian spy dossiers and hotel sex cameras. At some point we’re going to have a thrilling debate over the most scintillat­ing question in health care policy.

The Republican­s are going to try to replace Obamacare. They’re probably going to agree to cover everybody Obama covered, thus essentiall­y granting the Democratic point that health care is a right. But they are going to try to do it using more market-friendly mechanisms.

As you know, the American health care system is not like a normal market. When you make most health care decisions you don’t get much informatio­n on comparativ­e cost and quality; the personal bill you get is only vaguely related to the services; the expense is often determined by how many procedures are done, not whether the problem is fixed.

You wouldn’t buy a phone this way.

The Republican­s are going to try to introduce more normal market incentives into the process. They are probably going to rely on refundable tax credits and health savings accounts so everybody can afford to shop for their own insurance and care.

This would still be nothing like a free-market system — it would still be a highly regulated, largely public benefit — but it would rely more on consumer incentives.

The crucial question is: Do market incentives work in health care?

Most progressiv­es say markets don’t work. They point back to a famous essay the economist Kenneth Arrow wrote in 1963, in which he argued that there are several features that make health care unlike normal markets. People’s needs for health care are unpredicta­ble, unlike food and clothing. The doctorpati­ent relationsh­ip is unique and demands a high level of trust, empathy and care. Providers know much more about medicine than patients do, so the informatio­n is hopelessly asymmetric. Patients on a gurney can’t really make normal choices, and payment comes after care, not before.

These are all solid points. But health care has become less exceptiona­l over time. The internet and other mechanisms help customers acquire a lot more informatio­n. Sophistica­ted modeling helps with unpredicta­bility in a bunch of fields.

Proponents of market-based health care rely less on theory and more on data. The most fairminded review of the evidence I’ve read comes from a McKinsey report written by Penelope Dash and David Meredith. They noted that sometimes market forces lead to worse outcomes, but “we have been most struck by health systems in which provider competitio­n, managed effectivel­y, has improved outcomes and patient choice significan­tly, while at the same time reducing system costs.”

There’s much research to suggest that people are able to behave like intelligen­t health care consumers. Work by Amitabh Chandra of Harvard and others found higher-performing hospitals do gain greater market share over time. People know quality and flock to it.

Furthermor­e, health care providers work hard to keep up with the competitor­s. When one provider becomes more productive, the neighborin­g ones tend to as well.

There are plenty of examples where market competitio­n has improved health care delivery. The Medicare Part D program, passed under President George W. Bush, created competitio­n around drug benefits. The program has provided coverage for millions while coming in at 57 percent under the cost of what the Congressio­nal Budget Office initially projected. A study of Indiana’s health savings accounts found the state’s expenses were reduced 11 percent.

Laser eye surgery produces more patient satisfacti­on than any other surgery. But it’s generally not covered by insurance, so it’s a free market. Twenty years ago it cost about $2,200 per eye. Now I see ads starting at $250 an eye.

There’s a big chunk of evidence that market incentives would work in health care, especially in nonacute care. The harder problem for Republican­s may be political. This is a harried society. People may not want the added burdens of making health care decisions on top of all the others. This is a distrustfu­l society. People may not trust themselves or others to make decisions. This is an insecure society. People may not want what they perceive as another risk factor in their lives.

The policy case for the Republican plans is solid. Will they persuade in this psychologi­cal environmen­t? I doubt it.

Brooks is a New York Times columnist.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States