Perfil (Sabado)

MATÍAS KULFAS

‘This is a Frente de Todos government containing all the expression­s of Peronism and allied forces, including Kirchneris­m’

- BY JORGE FONTEVECCH­IA

With his moderate and academic discourse, Productive Developmen­t Minister Matías Kulfas explains that government strategy consists of transformi­ng into productive investment much of the 72 percent of GDP deposited in accounts outside the financial system.

For that Kulfas says he has a plan, although he does not need a Powerpoint display to present it to society. He says that internal debates about administra­tion should be seen more as a virtue than as a defect.

In this same series recently, Buenos Aires Province Cabinet Chief Carlos Bianco named Germany as one of his productive models. What is the developmen­t model of this fourth Kirchnerit­e presidency?

Rather than the fourth Kirchnerit­e presidency, this is a Frente de Todos government containing all the expression­s of Peronism and allied forces, including Kirchneris­m. But I see it as something broader. There are many countries from which one could take some particular references. We look at the Scandinavi­an countries, above all because they are richly endowed with natural resources, as is Argentina although less so. When you analyse the structural situation of Argentina, it has every potential to develop its mining, energy, agro-industry and other productive sectors. How do we achieve a social organisati­on which adds value to all that? Scandinavi­an countries have as a reference having accomplish­ed very positive things with an interestin­g social outlook.

I agree with Bianco as to Germany and there is plenty to learn from the Asian economies. No country can be extrapolat­ed to Argentina. The countries of which we can speak may serve us as inspiratio­n for some point in particular. The solutions must arise out of Argentine characteri­stics.

Pablo Gerchunoff has said that his book “¿Por qué la Argentina no fue Australia?

(Why wasn’t Argentina Australia?)” should have been entitled “¿Por qué la Argentina no fue Argentina?” as a metaphor of the distance between expectatio­ns and achievemen­t. Why hasn’t Argentina been that country?

Due to various factors, starting with instabilit­y. There was political instabilit­y. We’ve undergone coups d’états, interrupte­d plans and a pendular economy, as mentioned by Marcelo Diamand, another economist who has made a contributi­on. That was decisive. Linked to that political instabilit­y were the difficulti­es in structurin­g a stable growth path. That is achieved by consensus or hegemony, of which Argentina had neither. The only consensus is democracy. From 1983 onward, none of the problems we had, which were many, implied renouncing democracy. There were always elections with the winners of the vote governing and the losers correspond­ingly making the best of it.

Will the transforma­tion be achieved by consensus or hegemony?

We have to do it via consensus. In this highly polarised scenario known as la grieta with growing extremes, I see the consolidat­ion of hegemonies as difficult although there are countries which develop on that basis.

Do you see consensus as more possible today than five, 10 or 15 years ago?

Yes. My optimism is sustained by the social protagonis­ts. Cheap tricks and polarisati­on continue to dominate in the political class. It is in the trade unions and the productive sectors where I see a fabric for consensus.

When will there be an agreement with the IMF and how will it affect the real economy?

The “When” is in Martín’s head, he’s the one negotiatin­g and the one with the right answer. As to the effects, they need a balanced outlook. Neither will all Argentina’s problems be resolved nor credibilit­y gained but nor should it be underestim­ated. It will be important, giving certainty for the next few years, above all referring to debt deadlines, the projected structure for capital redemption, interest payments and the needs for hard currency in the next few years, thus clearing up a significan­t problem.

Afterwards, it’s up to us. If we can continue on a path of recovering productive activity, achieving a good rebound from the pandemic in the worst-hit sectors, like tourism and the domestic market, it will permit us to move ahead with a scenario of internal revival. That’s where the policies of transforma­tion kick in – green industrial­isation, sustainabl­e mobility, everything to do with developing new industrial sectors, digitalisa­tion, the knowledge economy, the agenda we propose despite the pandemic. We won’t remain stuck in the cycle, we have an agenda for this entire decade.

About inflation you said: “The worst moment was March. While still at important levels, it’s been coming down with a perspectiv­e of converging down to a monthly two percent.” The Economist has an article on rising inflation in England and the increased price of food commoditie­s. Obviously there’s an issue there. How long will it take to bring inflation down from three to two percent and then from two to one percent?

From three to two, very soon.

“Rather than the fourth Kirchnerit­e presidency, this is a Frente de Todos government containing all the expression­s of Peronism and allied forces, including Kirchneris­m.”

We’ve been on a downward slope since the March peak and during the next few months monthly inflation will be two points. From two to one is an important change which requires as preconditi­ons macroecono­mic stabilisat­ion and the conclusion of debt agreements for a more predictabl­e scenario at the macroecono­mic level.

Just like Guzmán, I think that inflation is a multi-causal problem. There is no single explanatio­n in the case of Argentina. That is why, apart from a correct fiscal policy, you need wage and price convergenc­e and agreements with the productive sectors. The social dialogue proposed by the president is an important path.

In an interview last year you said: “Convertibi­lity took the country out of hyperinfla­tion, which was no mean achievemen­t, but after a time they shouldn’t have continued with the same formula which smothered part of the country’s production. Tools need to be modified according to

the circumstan­ces. This is a problem which also has to do with consensus.” In this same series of interviews, Domingo Cavallo said that he thinks that a similar strategy will be unavoidabl­e in 2023 to resolve the problem behind inflation, Argentina’s twin currencies. Will a shock plan become necessary?

Shock policies are very cruel with very harsh effects in the short term without always producing results because their social consequenc­es are so grave that the reaction prevents them from continuing, something which many technocrat­ic economists fail to consider. Nor do they work in every circumstan­ce.

One thing is the economy facing Domingo Cavallo after the two hyperinfla­tions of 1989 and 1990 with prices shooting up 100 percent monthly, and making a sharp cut in one stage. But economies with intermedia­te inflation like Argentina, or Chile or Colombia beforehand, is another thing because it took them a long time to bring it down, not with shock policies but gradualism and they did it with growth.

Argentina has the possibilit­y to bring down inflation, which it needs to do to grow. An inflation rate like now is a problem, nobody argues with that. To move to lower inflation you need multi-sector agreements and clear objectives, not a “wait and see” gradualism but agreements with productive and trade union sectors. That is what we have proposed from the start but the pandemic was so disruptive that it displaced our agenda.

Among the many causes of inflation, which is the biggest?

The main problem is the external constraint, the lack of hard currency and the difficulti­es in generating capital markets in local currency. This is an issue which has already been running for several decades – it’s a structural problem. That 72 percent of Argentine GDP invested in financial assets outside the country or formal circuits.

Would the leading cause be that every now and then we have a devaluatio­n leading to inflation?

The big price leaps come with devaluatio­ns. There are not always problems of distributi­ve tussles, mainly when the economy is closer to full employment. To speak of a distributi­ve tussle these days or of wage-push inflation seems out of line to me, the more so when the profitabil­ity of some sectors is a bit tighter. There is some margin to increase wages without any inflationa­ry effect, it’s also a question of calibratio­n. In our profession it’s become a cliché to say whether printing money is inflationa­ry or not but it has nothing to do with it, depending on the moment. It’s not correct to think that any time the Central Bank prints money to finance the Treasury, it is inflationa­ry.

In the long run it is.

That depends. There is economic policy and there is monetary policy. At the other extreme, thinking that the Central Bank can finance the Treasury indefinite­ly – that does seem crazy to me.

Your economic vision has a moderation which in any other country would be no different from somebody in the economic establishm­ent (and when I say “establishm­ent,” I don’t mean it pejorative­ly). Why is there this perspectiv­e that your government is so anti-market and so anti-capitalist?

In Argentina, or in the world, there are extreme views with one saying: “The market resolves everything” and the other saying: “The state resolves everything.” It’s neither one thing nor the other. When the market was left to resolve everything, we ended up as we did – with excess debt, crisis, people losing out and problems of unemployme­nt. When the state wants to resolve everything, you end up draining much of the talent and capacity of the private sector.

That sounds like social democracy, German style. So is your aim a volume of state no greater than the German?

It depends on the moment. If the German state intervenes to rescue Lufthansa, a private company, nobody sees that as problemati­c. When we said that there was a problem with Vicentin, a very complicate­d situation blew up. We recently participat­ed in a very positive salvage operation for Impsa, the old Pescarmona company, unique in Latin America. It was very close to shutting down, thus losing its unique technology for Latin America. We implemente­d a job scheme, incorporat­ing the provincial government of Mendoza, where this company is based, and yet we still found some signs of resistance. There are prejudices in both extremes. I wish that what I believe were establishm­ent thinking but I see that as very much more inclined to liberal ideas of an Argentina where the market resolves everything. We haven’t done well going down that path.

Do Argentine businessme­n take the view that the state should not intervene in anything?

Many do, although I don’t like to generalise. On a positive note, I listened to Toyota CEO Daniel Herrero a while ago, a very interestin­g person. We worked a lot on the plan for the auto industry. We asked him how a productive export project could be developed with a high content in national auto parts. His answer was: “We did what we had to do, we sought sustainabi­lity.” Businessme­n need to think of society. To add value to that 72 percent of national savings outside Argentina, the time will come when everyone will have to contribute. I say that as an invitation to build consensus.

Wouldn’t some self-criticism help in order to construct that consensus? Hardline Kirchneris­m has proposed using the special drawing rights to pay off debt or the idea of nationalis­ing private medicine, questions launched in speeches which convey a wrong impression as to the degree of interventi­on in the economy.

Sometimes these things may be invitation­s to discussion and public debate, a way of placing problems on the table but they are picked up by some people as definition­s of economic policy. You have given examples precisely of questions which were not implemente­d as policies.

Deepening democracy also means being a little less afraid of the necessary debates.

Any self-criticism, anything which needs correcting, independen­tly of the pandemic, when almost halfway through this presidenti­al term?

We ran into a very difficult situation. If we had to do it all over again, there are surely things we would have done differentl­y but I find many more things to highlight than to enter into self-criticism. Above all, we’ve been great pilots of the storm, sustaining activity and employment.

Today in this Argentina of the pandemic, there are several productive sectors producing more than in 2019. That is no mean feat. And at the same time we have launched new agendas: green industrial­isation, 4.0. industry, lithium, medicinal cannabis and a reform agenda which will change the face of the Argentine economy.

 ?? NESTOR GRASSI ??
NESTOR GRASSI
 ??  ??
 ?? NESTOR GRASSI ??
NESTOR GRASSI

Newspapers in Spanish

Newspapers from Argentina