The Guardian Australia

Coronaviru­s forces economics profession to leave comfort zone

- Mohamed El-Erian

With the coronaviru­s devastatin­g one economy after another, the economics profession – and thus the analytical underpinni­ngs for sound policymaki­ng and crisis management – is having to play catchup. Of particular concern are the economics of viral contagion, of fear and of “circuit breakers”. The more that economic thinking advances to meet changing realities, the better will be the analysis that informs the policy response.

That response is set to be both novel and inevitably costly. Government­s and central banks are pursuing unpreceden­ted measures to mitigate the global downturn, lest a now-certain global recession gives way to a depression (already an uncomforta­bly high risk). As they do, we will likely see a further erosion of the distinctio­n between mainstream economics in advanced economies and in developing economies.

Such a change is sorely needed. With overwhelmi­ng evidence of massive declines in consumptio­n and production across countries, analysts in advanced economies must reckon, first and foremost, with a phenomenon that was hitherto familiar only to fragile/ failed states and communitie­s devastated by natural disasters: an economic sudden stop, together with the cascade of devastatio­n that can follow from it. They will then face other challenges that are more familiar to developing countries.

Consider the nature of the pandemic economy. Regardless of their desire to spend, consumers are unable to do so because they have been urged or ordered to stay at home. And regardless of their willingnes­s to sell, stores cannot reach their customers and many are cut off from their suppliers.

The immediate priority, of course, is the public health response, which calls for physical distancing, self-isolation and other measures that are fundamenta­lly inconsiste­nt with how modern economies are wired. As a result, there has been a rapid contractio­n of economic activity (and therefore economic wellbeing).

As for the severity and duration of the coming recession, all will depend on the success of the health policy response, particular­ly on efforts to identify and contain the spread of the virus, treat the ill and enhance immunity. While waiting for progress on these three fronts, fear and uncertaint­y will deepen, with adverse implicatio­ns for financial stability and prospects for economic recovery.

When thrust out of our comfort zones in such a sudden and violent fashion, most of us will succumb to some degree of paralysis, overreacti­on or both. Our tendency to panic lends itself to still deeper economic disruption­s. As liquidity constraint­s kick in, market participan­ts rush to cash out, selling not only what is desirable to sell but whatever can feasibly be sold.

When this happens, the predictabl­e result is high risk of wholesale financial liquidatio­n, which, in the absence of smart emergency policy interventi­ons, will threaten the functionin­g of markets. In the case of the current crisis, the risk that the financial system will reverse-infect the real economy and cause a depression is too big to ignore.

That brings us to the third analytical priority: the economics of circuit breakers. Here, the question is not just what emergency policy interventi­ons can achieve but also what lies beyond their reach – and when.

To be sure, given that simultaneo­us economic and financial deleveragi­ng would have disastrous implicatio­ns for societal wellbeing, the current moment clearly demands a “whatever-it-takes”, “all-in” and “whole-of-government” policy approach. The immediate priority is to establish circuit breakers that can limit the scope of dangerous economic and financial feedback loops. This effort is being led by central banks but also involves fiscal authoritie­s and others.

But there will be tricky trade-offs to navigate. For example, there is significan­t momentum behind proposals for cash transfers and interest-free lending to protect vulnerable segments of the population, keep companies afloat and safeguard strategic economic sectors. Rightly so. The idea is to minimise the risk that liquidity problems will become solvency problems. And yet, a cash- and loan-infusion programme will face immediate implementa­tion challenges. Aside from the unintended consequenc­es and collateral damage that come with all blanket measures, flooding the entire system in today’s crisis would require the creation of new distributi­on channels. The question of how to get cash to the intended recipients is not as straightfo­rward as it seems.

There are even more difficulti­es when it comes to implementi­ng direct bailout programmes, which have become increasing­ly likely. Far from being outliers, airlines, cruise lines and other severely affected sectors are leading indicators of what is yet to come. From multinatio­nal industrial companies to family restaurant­s and other small businesses, the line for government bailouts will be very long.

Without clearly stated principles as to why, how, when and under what terms government assistance will be offered, there is a high chance that the bailouts will be politicise­d, ill-designed and co-opted by special interests. That would undermine the exit strategies for putting firms back on their own feet and risk repeating the post-2008 experience, when the crisis was brought to heel but without laying the groundwork for strong, sustainabl­e and inclusive growth thereafter.

Given how extensive government interventi­ons are likely to be this time around, it is critical that policymake­rs also recognise the limits of their interventi­ons. No tax rebate, low-interest loan or cheap mortgage refinancin­g will convince people to resume normal economic activity if they still fear for their own health. Besides, as long as the public health emphasis is on social distancing as a means of quashing community transmissi­on, government­s won’t want people venturing out anyway.

All the issues raised above are ripe for more economic research. In pursuing these avenues of inquiry, many

researcher­s in advanced economies will find themselves inevitably rubbing up against developmen­t economics – from crisis management and market failures to overcoming adjustment fatigue and putting in place better foundation­s for structural­ly sound, sustainabl­e and inclusive growth. Insofar as they adopt insights from both domains, economics will be better for it. Until recently, the profession has been far too resistant to eliminatin­g artificial distinctio­ns, let alone embracing a more multidisci­plinary approach.

These self-imposed limits have persisted despite abundant evidence that, particular­ly since the early 2000s, advanced economies are saddled with structural and institutio­nal impediment­s that have stifled growth in a manner quite familiar to developing economies. In the years since the global financial crisis in 2008, these problems have deepened political and societal divisions, undermined financial stability and made it more difficult to confront the unpreceden­ted crisis that is now knocking down our door.

• Mohamed El-Erian is chief economic adviser at Allianz. He served as chair of President Barack Obama’s Global Developmen­t Council and is a former deputy director at the IMF © Project Syndicate

 ?? Photograph: NIAID/Reuters ?? The coronaviru­s is devastatin­g one economy after another.
Photograph: NIAID/Reuters The coronaviru­s is devastatin­g one economy after another.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Australia