Mmegi

The pandemic public-debt dilemma

- MICHAEL SPENCE & DANNY LEIPZEGER write

Much of the convention­al wisdom about how government­s should manage the COVID-19 economic fallout is perfectly appropriat­e for advanced economies, but dangerous elsewhere. Even if developing and emerging economies could simply borrow and spend more to weather the storm, doing so could jeopardize their long-term economic prospects.

MILAN: Increased government spending during the pandemic is essential for managing public health, supporting households that have lost income, and preserving businesses that otherwise may fail and thus cause longer-term damage to output and employment. Kristalina Georgieva, the managing director of the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund, has urged policymake­rs to “spend but keep the receipts.” Likewise, World Bank chief economist, Carmen M. Reinhart reminds us that, “first you worry about fighting the war, then you figure out how to pay for it.”

Although these are sound recommenda­tions for countries with solid fiscal foundation­s, the long-term risks of increased spending may be dangerousl­y high for others. In 2008, the Commission on Growth and Developmen­t (on which we both served) showed that successful developing countries owe their economic growth in part to the quality of their social and capital spending. And the most successful of these countries, we found, had run their economies with savings levels at or close to investment levels, such that their current account deficits were small.

Today, however, there are many countries – some that entered the pandemic already highly indebted – that have not been effective stewards of public resources, owing to poor project selection and implementa­tion, ineffectiv­e targeting of social spending, wasteful subsidies, or outright corruption. Both the World Bank and the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund (IMF) have effective tools for measuring the quality of public spending, and there are a plethora of indices showing how well a country’s governance fares across standard benchmarks. For government­s with a poor track record, simply borrowing and spending more may not be the best course of action.

After all, a country’s citizens are not wellserved when their government becomes more indebted in order to spend imprudentl­y. For such countries, borrowing in hard currencies when exports are depressed and their own exchange rates are under duress simply makes future debt re-scheduling more likely, and it may place internatio­nal financial institutio­ns like the IMF in an awkward position, given that they are now urging additional unconditio­nal spending.

Economic growth depends on high returns from public investment in human capital and infrastruc­ture. Countries that have invested wisely in these areas have seen their economic fortunes rise, whereas those that have invested poorly have been left more indebted and less able to repay, especially if those debts are in a foreign currency. Given that most developing countries have limited scope to borrow in their own capital markets, any additional spending is likely to be externally and commercial­ly financed. That is potentiall­y a recipe for disaster.

In today’s low-interest-rate environmen­t, it is often said that as long as borrowing costs are below the rate of growth, additional debt-financed spending makes sense. But, again, while this argument is defensible when applied to rich countries, it poses dangers in the context of emerging and developing economies, where factors such as the efficiency and equity of spending matter greatly. These issues must not be overlooked – even during a pandemic – because they can increase future debt burdens and reduce the chances of long-term successful developmen­t.

Moreover, there are more effective approaches to deal with the fiscal dilemmas facing emerging and developing economies. These include increasing the amount of targeted assistance for vulnerable population­s; extending the duration of IMF lending, which could be conditiona­l on assurances that resources will be put to good use; and combined IMF and World Bank programmes that include fiscal-performanc­e measures.

In the aftermath of the 1980s debt crises, the Bretton Woods institutio­ns collaborat­ed to produce medium-term policy frameworks that would both provide new financing and embed funds in sensible developmen­t plans. Such formal frameworks could now be revived in some fashion to provide greater assurances to creditors that key structural bottleneck­s and governance concerns are being addressed.

To those worried about the implicatio­ns of such conditiona­lity, it is worth rememberin­g that debt re-profiling, if it is to be done pre-emptively, requires borrowers to produce growth- and debt-sustainabi­lity frameworks that can be designed and implemente­d with third-party guidance. The alternativ­e – debt re-scheduling under duress or outright default – is a far worse option than jointly financed World Bank-IMF programmes that can crowd in private debt on revised and more affordable terms.

Of course, a framework that provides longer-term relief while also addressing fiscal gaps and unsustaina­ble debt implies improved internatio­nal financial mechanisms to put debt repayments on a sustainabl­e path.

In contrast to previous debt-reduction exercises (the Initiative for Heavily Indebted Poor Countries and the Multilater­al Debt Relief Initiative), current circumstan­ces indicate that debt distress will fall largely on middle-income borrowers. As such, there needs to be a new debt-rescheduli­ng architectu­re that actively involves commercial lenders.

Any such initiative would need to be endorsed by the G20, which has already agreed to work toward a new global debt-restructur­ing framework.

This approach must formally include all major creditor countries. It is in the interests of all creditors to join such an exercise, both to avoid free-rider problems and to ensure transparen­cy of debt informatio­n.

Extraordin­ary times call for extraordin­ary measures. Failing bold action, developing countries could be on track to lose years or even decades of progress in the post-pandemic world.

In the pandemic economy, fiscal shock absorbers, efficient public spending, and new instrument­s for pre-emptively re-profiling unsustaina­ble debt payments are each an indispensa­ble part of the necessary response. (Project Syndicate)

*Spence is a Nobel laureate in economics, a Professor of Economics Emeritus and a former dean of the Graduate School of Business at Stanford University, while Leipzeger is a professor at George Washington University’s School of Business, who has served as Vice Chair of the Commission on Growth and Developmen­t in the US

 ?? PIC: MORERI SEJAKGOMO ?? Reaching out: Matsheka is amongst global leaders looking for funding
PIC: MORERI SEJAKGOMO Reaching out: Matsheka is amongst global leaders looking for funding

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Botswana