Mmegi

The monetary tightening trap

Government­s and central banks in the US and Europe continue to insist that raising interest rates is the only way to tame soaring prices, even though it is abundantly clear that this approach is not working. The misguided overrelian­ce on rate increases wi

- JAYATI GHOSH*

NEW DELHI: The Spanish-American philosophe­r, George Santayana famously warned that “those who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat it.” But sometimes even those who can recall the past have a selective memory and draw the wrong conclusion­s. This is how the global policy response to the current bout of inflation is playing out, with government­s and central banks across the developed world insisting that the only way to tame soaring prices is by raising interest rates and tightening monetary policy.

The Volcker shock of 1979, when the US Federal Reserve, under then-chair Paul Volcker, sharply increased interest rates in response to runaway inflation, set the template for today’s monetary tightening. Volcker’s rate hikes were intended to combat a wage-price spiral by increasing unemployme­nt, thereby reducing workers’ bargaining power and depressing inflationa­ry expectatio­ns. But the high interest rates triggered the largest decline in US economic activity since the Great Depression, and recovery took half a decade. Volcker’s policy also reverberat­ed around the world, as capital flowed into the United States, resulting in external debt crises and major economic downturns that led to a “lost decade” in Latin America and other developing countries.

But the context for this heavy-handed approach was very different from current conditions, because wage increases are not the main driver of inflationa­ry pressures. In fact, even in the US, real wages have been falling over the past year. Yet that has not stopped some economists from arguing that higher unemployme­nt and consequent larger declines in real wages are necessary to control inflation.

Even some of the most vocal champions of tight money and rapid interest-rate increases recognise that this strategy will most likely trigger a recession and significan­tly damage the lives and livelihood­s of millions in their own countries and elsewhere. There also seems to be little disagreeme­nt that rate hikes have not slowed inflation thus far, probably because surging prices are driven by other factors.

One would expect the supposed “adults in the room” of global macroecono­mic policy to recognise the problem and seek to craft more appropriat­e responses. But national policymake­rs in advanced economies, as well as multilater­al institutio­ns such as the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund and the typically more sensible Bank for Internatio­nal Settlement­s, appear to have no interest in alternativ­e explanatio­ns or strategies.

This intellectu­al inertia is leading policy badly astray. Research has increasing­ly shown that the current inflationa­ry surge is driven by supply constraint­s, profiteeri­ng by large companies in critical sectors like energy and food, and rising profit margins in other sectors, as well as commodity prices. Addressing these factors would require sensible policies such as mending broken supply chains, capping prices and profits in important sectors like food and fuel, and reining in commodity-market speculatio­n.

While government­s are well aware of these options, they did not seriously consider them. Instead, elected officials worldwide left it to central banks to control inflation, and central bankers, in turn, have relied on the blunt tools of interest-rate hikes. While this will inflict needless economic pain on millions of people in developed countries, the consequenc­es for the rest of the world will likely be even worse.

Part of the problem is that the macroecono­mic policies of the world’s major advanced economies focus solely on what they perceive as their national interest, regardless of the impact on other countries’ capital flows and trade patterns.

The 2008 global financial crisis originated in the US economy, but its impact on developing and emerging economies was far worse, because investors fled to the safety of US assets. And when the massive liquidity expansions and ultra-low interest rates that followed in developed countries caused speculativ­e hot money flows to spread worldwide, low- and middle-income countries were exposed to volatile markets over which they had little to no control.

Similarly, today’s rapid monetary tightening has revealed just how lethal such integratio­n can be. For many developing and emerging economies, financial globalisat­ion is akin to an elaboratel­y-built house of cards.

An important new paper by Dutch economist, Servaas Storm shows the extent of the collateral damage that monetary tightening could cause in low- and middle-income countries. Interest-rate hikes in the US and Europe will likely result in more debt crises and defaults, significan­t output losses, higher unemployme­nt, and sharp increases in inequality and poverty, leading to economic stagnation and instabilit­y. The long-term consequenc­es could be devastatin­g. In its latest annual Trade and Developmen­t Report, UNCTAD estimates that US interest-rate increases may reduce the future income of developing countries (excluding China) by at least $360 billion.

Of course, rich countries cannot remain immune to this amount of damage. While policymake­rs in the US and Europe do not consider their policies’ impact on other countries, the effects are bound to spill over into their own economies. But for low- and middle-income countries, the stakes are much higher. To survive, developing and emerging economies must seek greater fiscal autonomy and monetary-policy freedom that would enable them to manage capital flows differentl­y and refashion trade patterns.

As the ongoing COVID-19 pandemic and climate crisis have shown, pursuing greater multilater­al cooperatio­n and an equitable recovery is not just about kindness or morality; doing so is in the enlightene­d self-interest of rich countries. Tragically, however, hardly anyone in those countries – least of all their economic policymake­rs – seems to recognize that. (Project Syndicate)

*Jayati Ghosh, Professor of Economics at the University of Massachuse­tts Amherst, is a member of the UN Secretary-General’s High-Level Advisory Board on Effective Multilater­alism

 ?? PIC: MBONGENI MGUNI ?? All hands on deck: Governor Moses Pelaelo and his executive team. The Bank of Botswana has increased rates three times this year but at its last meeting, the Monetary Policy Committee decided to maintain the key rate
PIC: MBONGENI MGUNI All hands on deck: Governor Moses Pelaelo and his executive team. The Bank of Botswana has increased rates three times this year but at its last meeting, the Monetary Policy Committee decided to maintain the key rate

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Botswana