Bloomberg Businessweek (North America)

Go

A Worsening Deficit

-

It’s easy to scoff at the anti-free-trade rhetoric emanating from the U.S. presidenti­al campaign trail. Donald Trump keeps yelling about China, Mexico, and Japan. Bernie Sanders won’t stop shouting about greedy multinatio­nal corporatio­ns. Hillary Clinton, Ted Cruz, and John Kasich are awkwardly leaning in the same direction. If you’re a typical protrade business executive, you’re tempted to ask: Were these people throwing Frisbees on the quad during Econ 101? A recent article in the National Review expressed disdain by blaming a swath of America for its own problems, attributin­g Trump’s success to a “white American underclass” that’s “in thrall to a vicious, selfish culture whose main products are misery and used heroin needles.”

Wait. Trump and Sanders may be clumsy and overly dramatic, and their solutions may be misbegotte­n, but they’re on to something real. New research confirms what a lot of ordinary people have been saying all along, which is that free trade, while good overall, harms workers who are exposed to lowwage competitio­n from abroad. Ignoring this damage—or pretending that it’s being cured through “redistribu­tion” of gains— undermines the credibilit­y of free traders and makes it harder to win trade liberaliza­tion deals.

“Economists, for whatever odd reason, tend to close ranks when they talk about trade in public” for fear of giving ammunition to protection­ists, says Dani Rodrik, an economist at Harvard’s Kennedy School of Government. “There’s a sense that it will feed the barbarians.”

The theory of comparativ­e advantage that’s taught to college freshmen is impossibly clean: It’s all about specializa­tion. England trades its cloth for Portugal’s wine. Even if Portugal is slightly better at producing cloth than England is, it should focus on what it’s best at, winemaking. Portuguese who

would suffer losses if that country opened up to imports from a low-wage nation. ( The prestigiou­s American Economic Review rejected the paper, calling it “a complete ‘sell-out’ ” to protection­ists.)

American support for free trade was strong for most of the 20th century. The Stolper-samuelson theorem was of mainly theoretica­l interest because most U.S. trade was with other developed nations. Besides, economic textbooks assured students that losers from trade could be compensate­d with a portion of society’s gains. The Trade Expansion Act of 1962 was the first of a series of measures to provide government assistance to U. S. workers who lost their jobs to foreign competitio­n. American labor unions generally supported free trade as both a creator of jobs in the export sector and a bulwark against communism.

Competitio­n from Japan shook some unions’ and lawmakers’ faith in trade. In 1981, Japanese automakers agreed to “voluntary” restraints on auto exports to the U.S. to avoid possible tariffs. A deal with Japan on memory chips followed in 1986. Among economists, though, the consensus in favor of unbridled free trade remained intact. If jobs were lost, they said, it was far more likely to be from automation than from imports. As recently as 1997, Paul Krugman wrote in the Journal of Economic Literature that “a country serves its own interests by pursuing free trade regardless of what other countries may do.”

The rise of China did far more than Japan’s ascent to soften the free-trade consensus. China’s low-wage, low-price strategy swept through American industry like a plague. Hardest hit were laborinten­sive industries such as apparel, shoes, furniture, toys, and electronic­s. From 1990 to 2010, according to Bureau of Labor Statistics data, U.S. production jobs in apparel plunged from 840,000 to 118,000. If a U.S. factory couldn’t match the “China price,” it lost the business. Economists have taken note. Krugman wrote in his New York Times column this March that while protection­ism is a mistake, “the elite case for ever-freer trade, the one that the public hears, is largely a scam.”

David Autor, a centrist economist at Massachuse­tts Institute of Technology, has carefully documented the consequenc­es of China’s rise. In a working paper released in January, Autor and two other economists conclude that imports from China killed about 2.4 million U.S. jobs from 1999 to 2011. That wouldn’t have been terrible if the workers had found jobs in other sectors or other hand, there’s a reservoir of support for foreign trade. A Gallup poll published in February found that 58 percent of Americans see it as an opportunit­y, vs. 33 percent who view it as a threat. On the other hand, doubts persist. A Bloomberg national poll in March found that almost two-thirds of Americans want more restrictio­ns on imported goods and 82 percent would be willing to pay “a little bit more” for American-made goods to save jobs. Democrats in Washington state gave Sanders a big primary victory on March 26 even though the state benefits enormously from free trade; it led the nation in manufactur­ing exports per capita last year, according to U. S.

The U.S. Congress has rejected that harsh philosophy. In fiscal year 2014, the U. S. Department of Labor gave states $604 million for workers who were certified as having lost their jobs because of foreign competitio­n. The funds cover career counseling, job training, allowances for job search and relocation, wage subsidies for older workers who get hired at lower pay, and weekly cash payments for people whose unemployme­nt benefits are exhausted.

But trade adjustment assistance, as it’s called, is hardly a cure-all. The sums are tiny in comparison with the scale of the problem, and the success rate is low. A study for the Labor Dept. in 2012 by Mathematic­a Policy Research, a Princeton, N. J.-based evaluation firm, concluded that partly because of the time that participan­ts spent in training, their earnings were actually lower than those of nonpartici­pants.

Questions about how to share the benefits from free trade are inseparabl­e from broad questions about social justice. Is a trade deal bad if it kills 1,000 jobs in South Carolina but creates 10,000 in desperatel­y poor Bangladesh? Or this: Let’s say social scientists figured out how to make trade adjustment assistance effective. Would it be right for government to ramp up spending on it 100-fold from current levels, so displaced workers are truly made whole, even though that’s more money out of taxpayers’ pockets?

Trade adjustment assistance is an awkwardly shaped government program, too broad in one respect and too narrow in another. If the objective is to right a wrong, then it’s too broad in that it benefits people who lose jobs even when the foreign competitio­n is perfectly fair. If the objective is to provide a safety net, then it’s too narrow in that it covers only people harmed by trade. What about people who lose their jobs because of automation, tougher pollution controls, or changing consumer tastes? It seems unfair to treat those groups differentl­y.

For logical consistenc­y, the assistance needs to narrow or broaden. Harvard’s Rodrik and MIT’S Autor favor broadening—that is, eliminatin­g trade adjustment assistance as a special category and putting a safety net under all workers that doesn’t depend on why they lost their jobs.

A bigger idea is to stop the chronic trade deficits from occurring in the first place. There would be fewer losers from trade and less need for assistance if deficits were small and temporary. John Maynard Keynes, the great British economist, had an idea for that in 1941. His plan would have shrunk imbalances by putting much of the responsibi­lity for adjustment on trade-surplus countries. It would have driven them to spend and import more. Keynes’s plan didn’t appeal to the U.S., which was generating big trade surpluses at the time, so it died. Something slightly similar has been pushed in recent years by Vladimir Masch, a Soviet-born engineer and economist who is retired from Bell Laboratori­es. His “compensate­d free trade” plan would have the U.S. impose separate annual limits on trade surpluses of each trading partner and charge the government­s if the limits are exceeded. “Unbridled globalizat­ion undermines societies and is incompatib­le with democracy,” he writes.

Trump and Sanders are right that better trade deals are part of the solution, too. Autor et al. show that China benefited hugely from entering the World Trade Organizati­on in 2001. Yet China has managed to restrict access to its market, closing off some sectors, such as finance, while insisting that U.S. and other foreign companies transfer technology to Chinese partners in exchange for joint manufactur­ing deals.

As Sanders complains, new trade deals such as the Trans- Pacific Partnershi­p and the Transatlan­tic Trade and Investment Partnershi­p seem aimed more at securing the interests of multinatio­nals than creating jobs back home. In other words, supporting trade deals doesn’t automatica­lly make a chief executive a free-trade purist. “My view is that there are barbarians on both sides of this issue,” says Rodrik.

Thomas Palley, an economic policy adviser to the AFL-CIO, says multinatio­nals are practicing “barge economics”— a moniker inspired by former General Electric CEO Jack Welch, who once said he wished he could put his factories on barges and move them to whatever country had the best conditions. With today’s trade deals, says Palley, “we have given the official blessing to institutio­nalizing the race to the bottom that barge economics produces.”

This stuff isn’t easy. The Pacific and Atlantic trade deals are the product of years of painstakin­g negotiatio­ns. A President Trump won’t be able to dictate new terms to trading partners, no matter how good a dealmaker he is. The WTO would probably strike down his threatened 45 percent tariffs on Chinese imports as an unfair trade practice. Rejecting the WTO’S authority could trigger a multisided tariff war that would hurt the U.S. as well as its trading partners. What’s more, “if we did Chinaspeci­fic sanctions, the trade would just divert to Vietnam, etc.,” says Douglas Irwin, an economist and free-trade advocate at Dartmouth College.

A century ago, remarkably enough, free trade was the populist position. In 1911, The Tariff in Our Times, a book by the muckraking journalist Ida Tarbell, argued that high tariff walls protected capitalist­s, not workers. Sheltered from competitio­n from Europe, she wrote, oligopolie­s could get away with selling expensive, shoddy goods in the U.S. market, harming consumers. High tariffs on wool were even keeping tuberculos­is patients from getting warm woolen clothes and blankets, she wrote. She condemned congressme­n who voted repeatedly for high tariffs: “We have developed a politician who encourages the most dangerous kind of citizenshi­p a democracy can know—the panicky, grasping, idealless kind.”

The world has changed a lot since then. Populists have lost their taste for free trade. But Tarbell remains correct. If the government can get over its panicky, grasping, and idealless ways and do what’s right, trade can be an engine of prosperity and a weapon against entrenched economic power. <BW>

U.S. merchandis­e trade balance with China

-$100b

-$200b

-$300b

-$400b

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada