Calgary Herald

Conservati­ves should be OK with a carbon tax

Their principles lead to that conclusion, says Jim Farney.

-

Conservati­ve politician­s across Canada have strongly opposed the Trudeau government’s promise to impose carbon tax since the idea was floated in 2015. Beginning with Premier Brad Wall in Saskatchew­an, opposition to the carbon tax is now a central commitment of conservati­ve premiers Brian Pallister, Scott Moe and Doug Ford, as well as the leader of the official Opposition, Andrew Scheer.

It is easy to see how conservati­ves would oppose a new tax created by the federal government. After all, what’s more conservati­ve than opposing a new federal tax? Dig deeper down into conservati­ve principles, though, and it is hard to see where those conservati­ve principles point except towards a carbon tax.

This is counter-intuitive, but conservati­sm in Canada is a rope wound out of four different strands: traditiona­list conservati­ves, religious conservati­ves, free market conservati­ves and conservati­ve populists. The first two strands provide reasons to be concerned about climate change. The last two provide important reasons why a carbon tax is the appropriat­e mechanism to use to reduce emissions.

Traditiona­lists are the type of conservati­ve that dictionari­es define as “Tory.” In Canada, they are personifie­d by Robert Stanfield, Hugh Segal or Peter Lougheed. They advocate for a strong government able to pursue the collective interest. But they limit the scope of what government does. They have long argued that the growth associated with unrestrain­ed capitalism damages local communitie­s.

Religious conservati­ves usually make the news for their positions on social issues such as euthanasia or abortion. But all of the major religious traditions in Canadian society have well worked out traditions of social thought that cover the waterfront of political, economic and social issues. Over the last generation, all of these traditions have increasing­ly stressed the importance of environmen­tal stewardshi­p.

This leaves us with free market conservati­ves and populists — the largest and most politicall­y important strands of conservati­sm in Canada today. They part company with traditiona­lists or religious conservati­ves on the importance of environmen­tal issues. But both types make powerful arguments about how government ought to pursue public goods that have important implicatio­ns for how to approach climate change.

Free market conservati­ves, almost by definition, hold true to a central gospel: setting prices through the marketplac­e is an extraordin­arily efficient way to allocate scarce resources. They don’t like taxes. However, they recognize the good that can come from a transparen­t tax, imposed fairly for a demonstrab­le social good.

Free market conservati­ves will argue cap and trade or carbon rationing requires a much more robust level of government interventi­on. And such taxes would destroy the market’s ability to communicat­e value accurately through setting prices. As such, they create winners and losers. A transparen­t tax, like the carbon tax, they might argue, treats all emissions equally. In so doing, it preserves the market’s inherent ability to accurately set the most efficient price.

This leaves populists. If by populist we mean popular, then premiers Moe and Ford have hit pay dirt. But, if we mean populist in the way that Canada’s most notable conservati­ve populist, Preston Manning, defined the term, then we come to a different position. Manning emphasized that to be populist was to create mechanisms that allow ordinary people to bring their wisdom to bear on the making of public policy.

Recognizin­g the carbon cost of consumptio­n decisions is a direct and transparen­t way to involve ordinary people in collective decisions. We end up in the same place as free market arguments. Indeed, Manning himself publicly supports a carbon tax.

So what we are left with are two arguments often made by conservati­ves but which, strictly speaking, are not conservati­ve. One is jurisdicti­onal: that this is a policy area in which the provinces ought to take the lead and not the federal government. Ultimately, this question will be decided by the courts. The other is regional: that a carbon tax which hurts provinces like Alberta and Saskatchew­an more than Quebec is unfair.

These are important questions. Answering them may tell us which government should do something about Canada’s carbon emissions. But it is inescapabl­e that the “what should be done,” if it were to be done by conservati­ves, would have to look remarkably like a carbon tax. Jim Farney is an associate professor of politics at the University of Regina, author of Social Conservati­ves and Party Politics in Canada and the United States and co-editor of Conservati­vism in Canada. He’s also a contributo­r with EvidenceNe­twork.ca based at the University of Winnipeg.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada