Edmonton Journal

Politician­s should aim for growth, not diversific­ation

- JACK M. MINTZ Jack M. Mintz is the Palmer Chair at the University of Calgary’s School of Public Policy.

For decades, Alberta politician­s have waved the wand to diversify the economy in various ways and have generally failed to do so.

It is hard to overcome market forces since profitabil­ity has a lot more to do with millions of individual interactio­ns than any one public decision. King Canute tried to sit by the shore to turn away the tide, but his legs got wet anyway.

No doubt energy is the dominant industry in Alberta, even more so today. It involves not just extraction, but many manufactur­ing and service firms that are tied to the success of the oil and gas industry. About half of the Alberta economy relies on the energy industry and most of the product is sold in North America.

Yet, politician­s keep focusing on diversific­ation as an objective, whether achievable or not. Some push for upgrading of bitumen into synthetic oil or refined products for export — in other words, product diversific­ation.

Politician­s have sought industrial diversific­ation by investing in alternativ­e industries unrelated to the oil and gas sector. Others argue for geographic­al diversific­ation by developing alternativ­e markets besides the United States.

So how do we evaluate whether diversific­ation can be successful or not?

Take first the argument for upgrading, which is typically based on job creation. Upgrading is very capital intensive, requiring billions added in new capacity. It is cheapest to upgrade product in existing refineries such as Quebec and New Brunswick, or the U.S. Gulf Coast, compared with building new capacity.

Thus, at present, very few firms are willing to build upgraders in Alberta except for the North West project, with the private producers being paid a toll (up to a limit in operationa­l and capital costs), leaving to the Alberta government market risks associated with uncertain refining margins.

If the provincial government subsidizes or regulates upgrading in Alberta, it is presumed that the “value-added” jobs created in the sector will create indirect jobs elsewhere, assuming such resources are freely available to grow the economy. The problem with typical analysis of this sort is that it ignores economic resource constraint­s. Clearly, this is not the case in Alberta with a very low unemployme­nt rate and skilled labour shortages.

More upgrading of energy product will require additional labour and other productive inputs taken away from other sectors of the economy. This will bid up costs, not just in the upgrading sector, but other sectors of the economy. In other words, additional upgrading could undermine industrial diversific­ation.

If businesses determined that it is best to reallocate resources from other sectors to the energy sector, this could increase incomes in the economy since more profitable opportunit­ies are being pursued. However, if King Canute-like government­s try to redirect resources from one sector to the other, beyond what is achievable in markets, it will force labour and other resources to be deployed in less profitable opportunit­ies.

This argument carries over to policies aimed at diversifyi­ng the industrial structure. Government­s bear considerab­le risk if they try to push for sectors that are not viable. Whether Newfoundla­nd cucumber plants, Nova Scotia auto plants or Alberta hazardous waste treatment centres, the world is awash with industrial diversific­ation policies that failed, costing taxpayers billions of dollars as well as lining the pockets of industrial­ists pushing for subsidies. Even if the sector grows jobs, resources are not being put to their more economic use.

Geographic­al diversific­ation of product markets is similarly difficult to achieve in the presence of transport and communicat­ion costs. It is cheapest to export oil to the United States compared with Asia since prices net of transport costs can be highest for Alberta producers. Nonetheles­s, transport infrastruc­ture is costly to build and market pricing can result at times in better returns by exporting to some far away markets than closer ones.

There are policies that can help build a more diversifie­d economy without government­s trying to pick the winners (and more likely, the losers).

For example, a general tax reform that reduces taxes on investment and savings can help diversify the economy substantia­lly through market forces responding to lower taxation. The removal of regulation­s that impede sectors from growing would also be sensible to achieve.

Much of the growth would leverage off the skills of Albertans, including those developed in the energy industry. Thus, supporting innovation and education can help spur new industries eventually.

The recent cutbacks and tuition fee freezes in post-secondary education are not the way to achieve diversific­ation.

At times, other considerat­ions are involved. One argument that I have made in favour of geographic­al diversific­ation of Canadian trade is to better our negotiatio­n stance with respect to the U.S. With alternativ­es, we have a credible threat to withstand disputes, whether in softwood lumber or “Buy American” policies.

Diversific­ation itself should not be a politician’s objective. Instead, it should be growth and better incomes for Albertans.

It is better to put in place the right macro-environmen­t and let businesses sort out market opportunit­ies

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada