National Post

Kyoto is not the answer

- COLBY COSH

On Monday, Thomas C. Schelling of the University of Maryland was awarded a halfshare of the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences. That’s the honour often (inaccurate­ly) called the Nobel economics prize. Schelling has been a major figure in the progress of game theory from an abstract mathematic­al plaything to a tool of genuine power, one relied upon routinely by diplomats, generals, and his fellow economists. He has influenced everything from addiction research to the screenplay of Stanley Kubrick’s Dr. Strangelov­e.

But not everyone will be happy about Schelling’s elevation to the supreme rank of world scholarshi­p. In the early 1990s, Schelling — having long since completed the wide-ranging applied math that made him Nobelizabl­e — became interested in the debate over climate change. He has since made his own controvers­ial contributi­ons that place him in a littleinte­llectual territory between the prophets of doom and the global-warming skeptics.

Schelling accepts the mainstream theory of global warming: that it is happening, that humans are contributi­ng to it significan­tly and that the resulting change will probably be unpreceden­ted in size. What makes Schelling unusual is that he is pretty comfortabl­e with the increasing heat. He was among the first to argue that climate catastroph­ists underrate the adaptabili­ty of human beings and their economic arrangemen­ts. The net temperatur­e change in any one place, he notes, is unlikely to exceed or even approach the changes people cope with whenever they move between two distant parts of the world. Travelling from Winnipeg to Miami doesn’t kill anybody, and despite very different weather, people in both places live by the same means and enjoy roughly the same quality of life.

Scientists expect that the mean global temperatur­e will rise, say, two or three degrees between now and 2080. In 1992, Schelling asked readers of the American Economic Review to perform a thought experiment: If such a rise in temperatur­e had already happened, would we now look back on it with horror and sadness? Would older people even have been aware of it, amidst the other dizzying changes that characteri­zed the 20th century? It’s most likely, Schelling postulated, that even a farmer would cite other factors — automobile­s, electricit­y, the telephone, modern pesticides and fertilizer­s — as having altered his life more than a long, slow shift in the growing season.

Schelling acknowledg­es a chance that small, gradual changes in the world climate could cause fast-developing catastroph­es in some places. And we may have other reasons to resist a rise in the global temperatur­e. But on the whole, he contends, the only major human activity seriously threatened by climate change is agricultur­e. In the advanced industrial democracie­s, where agricultur­e has become a trivial fraction of national economic output, dealing with rising temperatur­es as they arrive will be relatively cheap. But climate change would hit the developing world, and especially subsistenc­e farmers, relatively hard.

So what should the rich nations do to help others prepare? Schelling has been skeptical about the political prospects for a global carbon tax, thinks tradeable emission permits are elegant but impractica­l, and was an early critic of the Kyoto Protocol. As a young man, he worked on the postwar Marshall Plan that rehabilita­ted Europe. The Plan worked wonders without any imposed targets, any explicit performanc­e criteria, or any regime of penalties for inefficien­t use of America’s gigadollar­s. Schelling thinks it’s the way to go if we want to pay the developing world to help deal with the effects of global warming — such as moving people away from coastal cities, which will increasing­ly be at risk of flood as water levels rise.

Still, even a Marshall Plan for global warming may take a back seat to other priorities. The ideal policy goal may simply be to reduce the poor countries’ dependence on agricultur­al output by helping them not be poor. According to Schelling’s view, the spread of liberty and free trade may be the best environmen­tal medicine. Schelling also contribute­d to the creation of last year’s “Copenhagen consensus,” a much-vilifed exercise in ranking potential worldwide crises by their urgency and solvabilit­y. Under the leadership of a Danish political scientist Bjørn Lomborg, Schelling and other senior economists crunched the data and came to an agreement that foreign aid should probably be committed first to fighting AIDS, to improving nutrition and sanitation, and to encouragin­g smallbusin­ess formation. Climate projects, like Kyoto, were condemned as poor value for money.

Schelling’s work in this field has been nuanced, insightful, and daring, which is to say that it’s been everything most environmen­tal talk is not. Partisans on both sides of the climate issue could learn much from his analytical speculatio­ns — and still more from the lucid, bold way he expresses them.

 ??  ??
 ?? TIM SLOAN / AFP / GETTY IMAGES ?? Thomas C. Schelling at the University of Maryland on Monday, after winning the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economics.
TIM SLOAN / AFP / GETTY IMAGES Thomas C. Schelling at the University of Maryland on Monday, after winning the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economics.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada