National Post

More CPP, less RRSP

Mandatory CPP increases have unintended consequenc­es

- CHARLES LAMMAM, JA SON CLEMENS, AND MILAGROS PALACIOS Charles Lammam, Jason Clemens, and Milagros Palacios are co-authors of RRSPs and an Expanded Canada Pension Plan available at www.fraserinst­itute.org

The idea of expanding the Canada Pension Plan (CPP) resurfaced in december 2012 during a meeting of the federal and provincial finance ministers. The ministers agreed to explore possible reforms to the CPP at their next meeting expected sometime in the coming months.

The proposal getting the most attention is a mandatory expansion of the CPP. Such a change would require working Canadians to contribute more of their income today via payroll taxes with the promise of greater benefits in retirement. unfortunat­ely, the debate thus far has ignored a critical economic insight that leads proponents of an expanded CPP to overestima­te the increase in overall retirement savings and therefore the benefits of this policy reform.

economic theory tells us that higher forced savings for retirement through the CPP will lead Canadians to reduce their voluntary savings elsewhere. That means an expanded CPP would not increase overall retirement savings to the extent expected but it would change the mix with more going to CPP and less to other savings like Registered Retirement Savings Plans (RRSPs).

The economic framework for analyzing how people consume and save traces back to the work of Nobel economist Milton Friedman and others. Friedman’s work concluded that people choose how much to spend (consume) and save based on their expectatio­ns of income over the course of their lifetime. If people’s preference­s for spending vs. savings don’t change, and if they don’t expect more income over their lifetime, they will simply offset increased government-mandated savings with less voluntary savings, leaving the overall amount saved largely unchanged.

Thankfully, Canadians don’t have to rely solely on theory since we have a natural experiment with mandatory increases to CPP contributi­ons. Specifical­ly, the CPP payroll tax increased to 9.9% in 2003 from 5.0% in 1993. Those increases give us an opportunit­y to observe the actual response of Canadians who save voluntaril­y in RRSPs.

Our recent study looked at CPP and RRSP contributi­ons for two age groups: Canadians under 45 and aged 45 to 65. It further separated each age group into two income groups: $10,000 to $50,000 and $50,000 to $100,000. We particular­ly focused on the 45-65 age group making between $10,000 to $50,000 since this group is likely the most sensitive to changes in the CPP because of their age and income. using three different measures, our analysis consistent­ly found RRSP contributi­ons declined as mandatory savings to the CPP increased.

For instance, the percentage of taxfilers aged 45 to 65 with income between $10,000 and $50,000 contributi­ng to RRSPs declined between 1993 and 2003. Specifical­ly, 40.2% of tax-filers in this group contribute­d to RRSPs in 1993 and the proportion fell to 33.0% by 2003.

We found similar results when exam-

With RRSPs, the assets accumulate­d over time can be fully transferre­d to a beneficiar­y upon death

ining the share of income contribute­d to RRSPs (see the figure elsewhere on this page). Again, for Canadians aged 45 to 65 with income between $10,000 and $50,000, the share of income contribute­d to RRSPs declined to 3.5% in 2003 from 4.4% in 1993. Meanwhile, the share contribute­d to CPP doubled to 3.0% from 1.5% of income as the CPP payroll tax was raised.

A third measure showed the dollar value of RRSP contributi­ons per tax-filer also decreased as mandatory CPP contributi­ons increased. Taken together, our findings strongly suggest a substituti­on between CPP and RRSPs occurred in the past when mandatory CPP contributi­ons increased, as basic economic theory would predict.

The debate about the benefits of increasing the CPP contributi­on rate for all workers would then, at a minimum, account for the costs of reduced RRSP savings, which include a loss of flexibilit­y and choice.

With RRSPs, the assets accumulate­d over time can be fully transferre­d to a beneficiar­y upon death (the CPP only offers scaled-back benefits to survivors). Moreover, if you’re young and interested in buying a house, RRSPs through the Home Buyers’ Plan can help by allowing penalty and tax-free withdrawal­s up to $25,000. Similarly, if you’re middle-aged and looking to transition to a new field of work, the Lifelong Learning Plan allows you to withdraw RRSP savings up to $10,000 per year penalty and tax free. Finally, if you have a terminal illness or need emergency funds, you can use RRSP savings.

These benefits are lost when Canadians are forced to save more in CPP and then offset those increases with decreases in their RRSPs. Other aspects of this trade-off, such as the comparativ­e benefits of the CPP (defined benefit in retirement) compared with the benefits of RRSPs (flexibilit­y and choice), also need to be assessed and discussed.

The key to providing retirement income through savings is a set of rules that allows for an optimal mix of savings for different people in different stages of life and with different preference­s. There may be benefits to a compulsory expansion of the CPP, but these benefits need to be weighed against the costs, which as our analysis shows could include a reduction in voluntary RRSP savings.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada