National Post

Creating ‘global firefighte­rs’

- Jeffrey D. Sachs The New York Times Jeffrey D. Sachs is special adviser to the United Nations secretary general on the Millennium Developmen­t Goals and director of the Earth Institute at Columbia University.

Natural disasters like the devastatin­g earthquake in Nepal constitute a highly uncertain but quantifiab­le risk. No one can say for sure when a major earthquake will strike. But the fault lines are known. We need a new global system of disaster insurance, akin to how homeowners guard against calamity.

Relief teams and millions of dollars of aid are arriving in Nepal, but despite the best of intentions, emergency operations will be a desperate patchwork, and long-term rebuilding will be hampered by lack of funds, donor fatigue and red tape. That’s what happened in Haiti after the 2010 earthquake, in the Philippine­s after a string of recent typhoons, and in the West Africa Ebola epidemic. We need a better approach.

Even poor countries can take precaution­s, especially if internatio­nal organizati­ons help them to do it. Think of commercial airline safety, which, though not flawless, is high even in the poorest regions in the world. There is an integrated system that connects airplane manufactur­ers, airline companies, air-traffic controller­s, global insurers and national and global regulators.

Catastroph­es like earthquake­s, typhoons, droughts, floods and epidemics pose quantifiab­le risks. These risks can’t be specified with the actuarial precision that underlies home and life insurance, but there is enough precision to allow for insurance coverage. For hundreds of years, Lloyd’s and other insurers have been diversifyi­ng the risks of even one-time events; natural hazards like earthquake­s are not one-time events, but occurrence­s that return with calculable probabilit­ies.

Suppose Nepal’s government could have gone shopping for earthquake insurance to cover the large-scale losses and publicsect­or response after a disaster. Potential underwrite­rs would examine the probabilit­ies of earthquake­s at various magni- tudes, using the historical record, seismic modelling and assessment­s of the vulnerabil­ities of the buildings.

The leading insurer, generally a reinsuranc­e company, would then sell off its excess exposure to Nepal’s earthquake risk to other insurance companies, or even capital markets around the world via so-called catastroph­e bonds and similar instrument­s. These risk carriers would receive part of Nepal’s premium payments, and be required to pay out to Nepal in the event of an earthquake. Nepal would be financiall­y protected, and insurers would diversify the risk.

The original insurance underwrite­r would have made demands of Nepal, that it implement cost-effective earthquake-preparedne­ss measures, like updated building and zoning codes; a disaster response plan; and emergency health systems. These steps would limit expected damages caused by natural disaster — and lower the premium and expected payout. Over time, underwriti­ng benchmarks would be standardiz­ed around the world.

Most low-income countries and some rich ones as well are woefully unprepared for the quantifiab­le catastroph­ic risks they face, whether seismologi­cal shocks, climate-related catastroph­es or epidemics. After each disaster, the afflicted countries and United Nations agencies must call on other countries to make ad hoc pledges of funds and response teams; there’s no global equivalent of the fire department. It’s often too little, too late.

How would a disaster insurance system work? World-leading reinsurers, such as Swiss Re, Munich Re and others, would bid to provide countries with the service. Government­s would pay annual premiums, linked to actuarial assessment­s of risks, with internatio­nal donor agencies like the World Bank helping to share the costs, based on the resources of the insured countries. For some large and unpredicta­ble risks, where the private sector alone won’t provide cover, additional official financing would be blended with private funds, similar to what takes place in the United States with flood and crop insurance.

Cost-sharing with internatio­nal agencies l i ke the World Bank would have to be attractive enough for poor countries to obtain coverage on reasonable terms. For highincome donor countries, the upside would be a global system with reduced vulnerabil­ity and with less need to provide ad hoc post-disaster aid.

Insurance would reveal how vulnerable certain parts of the world are to rising costs of disasters, including those associated with global warming. But at least we’d be able to begin to account for this. It would provide a powerful way to drive mitigation and adaptation investment­s, a point emphasized in recent years by Rowan Douglas of the insurer Willis Group.

A global system of disaster insurance would of course not be perfect and would take time to implement, but could save many lives and livelihood­s in the years ahead, and help vulnerable lowincome countries like Haiti and Nepal chart a path to sustainabl­e developmen­t.

Every internatio­nal disaster leads to a rush, ad hoc response. We need to do better than this … and insurance is the place to start

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada