National Post

Much to resolve with voting reform

- Andrew Coyne

What exactly are the Liberals up to on electoral reform? The party was elected on a platform that pledged, in part, to ensure that “2015 will be the last federal election conducted under the first-past-the-post voting system .” To that end it promised to appoint an allparty parliament­ary committee to review the options for reform, with legislatio­n to follow “within 18 months of forming a government.”

Yet here we are, five months after cabinet was sworn in, and the committee has yet to be struck. While Maryam Monsef, the Minister of Democratic Institutio­ns, is believed to be committed to the project, the suspicion lingers that more powerful figures in the prime minister’s office would not be overly concerned if it died the same death as other Liberal promises.

To be fair, the slow start may be rooted in genuine uncertaint­y over how to proceed. They can’ t just renege, of course: not on such an explicit promise, or on such a major issue. Neither can they simply ram through their own preferred option, given the obvious partisan sensitivit­ies involved. Either course would poison the rest of this Parliament, and make the new government look every bit as cynical and despotic as the government it replaced.

But suppose you were genuinely interested in giving a fair hearing to the alternativ­es, gathering consensus, and consulting the public, such that the final result, if not to everyone’s liking, was at least seen as legitimate? How would you go about it?

Is the usual parliament­ary committee, dominated as it is by the governing party, enough? Or should the parties be represente­d, as the NDP has suggested, in proportion to their share of the popular vote? Should the process be taken out of the hands of the parties altogether, whether through a royal commission or an assembly of ordinary citizens?

And that’s just the start. How should whatever was proposed be ratified? Many have suggested a referendum is in order. Fine: on what? Should the public be asked to approve a particular reform proposal, or choose between a menu of options? By what voting system? With what majority? And so on?

These are all knotty questions. Still, it should be possible to narrow things down a bit. We are not starting from scratch here, after all. Recent years have seen two major consultati­ve exercises on electoral reform, in British Columbia and Ontario, both involving citizens’ assemblies. We can build on their work.

And while the theoretica­l possibilit­ies are limitless, in the broad stroke the design of electoral systems comes down to how you answer a couple of large questions. First, should it be “winner take all,” in which only the winning candidate in each riding is elected, or proportion­al?

Put another way, should ridings be represente­d by one member or several — since it is by dividing a riding’s representa­tion among several members, in proportion to their share of the popular vote, that proportion­ality is achieved.

Second, should voters simply mark an x beside the candidate (or candidates) of their choice, or should they rank them in order of preference ( 1, 2, 3 …), a system known as ranked or preferenti­al voting?

And third, how might these be combined? Any system of single- member districts, for example, is “winner take all”: the only difference between first past the post and ranked balloting in this regard is whether a simple plurality or majority of the vote is sufficient.

Multi- member voting models differ mostly in how many members are elected from each district. Combine ranked balloting with relatively small districts, say five members, and you get the “single transferab­le vote” ( STV) system in use i n, for example, Ireland. Make the districts larger and f ewer, and combine them with single- member ridings, and the result is the “mixed member proportion­al” (MMP) model, as used in New Zealand.

There are further possible combinatio­ns. STV can include some singlememb­er districts, where the ridings would otherwise be dauntingly large. MMP, for its part, is often said to require the use of lists of candidates drawn up by party leaders. But in fact this is not so. Who gets on a party’s list can be decided by a vote of party members at large; voters, likewise, need not be obliged to vote for a party’s slate, but can vote directly for the candidates of their choice from each list.

Assuming we deci de this by referendum, how then should we proceed? I’d argue we can eliminate one option off the top: the status quo. Not only did the Liberals explicitly run on its abolition, but so did the NDP, the Greens and Bloc. So while it is true the Liberals do not have a mandate for any particular reform, i t would seem perfectly democratic to make the referendum question a choice between reform models, rather than between reform or the status quo.

I suspect a preliminar­y canvassing of opinion will pretty quickly find support divides into the three broad camps I mentioned: ranked ballots ( i. e., in single- member districts), STV, and MMP. Let teams of parliament­arians, then, assemble around these, with instructio­ns to hammer out a detailed proposal for each to put to the people.

Finally, it would be pretty odd to choose a reform using t he f i rst- past- thepost system of voting, with t he spectre of whatever emerged slipping through with the support of 40 per cent or less of the public. So to ensure reform has broad public support, why not decide the referendum using a ranked ballot?

Over to you, Liberals.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada