National Post

A PRODUCTIVI­TY BOOM LOOMS.

- WI L L I A M WAT S O N

How correlated do you think productivi­ty gains are from decade to decade? In other words, does productivi­ty growth this decade mean more or less productivi­ty growth next?

It’s a trick question: Turns out they aren’t correlated. In a new paper on “the modern productivi­ty paradox,” three business- school profs ( two from MIT, one from Chicago) correlate U. S. productivi­ty growth rates in adjacent, rolling 10- year periods over the last half century and find the graph is a random scatter of points, with the formal statistica­l tests revealing no significan­t correlatio­n. That’s true both for labour productivi­ty — total output divided by the number of workers — and “total factor productivi­ty,” the overall gain in output after taking into account both greater labour and greater capital inputs.

The three economists ( Erik Brynjolfss­on, Daniel Rock and Chad Syverson) read that lack of correlatio­n from decade to decade as good news. We’ve just been through a decade of pretty lousy productivi­ty growth. If decade results were positively correlated, this last down decade would augur another down decade, which in fact lots of people seem to be predicting. The paper’s authors are a lot more upbeat. The algorithms are coming, they argue. They believe artificial intelligen­ce ( AI), which is just gathering steam, is going to have a transforma­tive effect. ( AI is fine so far as it goes but I wonder if we’ll ever get “AW” or “AM”: artificial wisdom and artificial morality. The humanborne versions don’t seem to be doing that well these days.)

Like the first round of computeriz­ation in the 1970s and 1980s, AI isn’t yet juicing better productivi­ty numbers. But we’ve seen this movie before. In 1987, MIT’s Robert Solow, who won that year’s Nobel Prize in economics, became even more famous with his quip that “We see computers everywhere except in the productivi­ty statistics.” That spawned a lot of economic literature trying to figure out why. Was it a problem of incorrect measuremen­t? Was it a quest i on of f alse hopes? Were the widespread, transforma­tive applicatio­ns that everyone assumed were coming simply not meant to be?

Brynjolfss­on, Rock and Syverson argue there’s some truth in all these explanatio­ns. On mea s u r e ment , for instance, there’s a problem that much of the “output” of smartphone­s in terms of usefulness, enjoyment and diversion simply doesn’t get counted in GDP: Google Maps, for instance, is given away free despite its immense value. And there’s the complicati­on that obsessive diversion smartphone and Internet users enjoy at work may actually reduce traditiona­l GDP.

But mainly, the economists think, the problem is timing. In fact, the productivi­ty paradox involving computers was solved not long after Solow discovered it. Productivi­ty boomed through the 1990s as computers became commonplac­e in the workplace. That’s not unusual. Transforma­tive technologi­es usually take time to diffuse through an economy. The Industrial Revolution, based on steam, took several decades to build up its own steam. As for electricit­y, one wellknown study noted that “half of US manufactur­ing establishm­ents remained unelectrif­ied until 1919, about 30 years after the shift to polyphase alternatin­g current began.”

It seems likely the AI revolution is going through a similar latent phase before taking off. It’s even possible that in these early stages new technologi­es are a drag on productivi­ty growth. Lots of money, brainpower and effort goes into them but with no shortterm payback. Driverless cars seem to really be coming, but they’re not here yet ( even if Uber’s said it’s buying 34,000 of them from Volvo starting in 2019). For the last few years, tens of thousands of well- paid people have been busy developing driverless cars but they’re still not developed quite yet.

When they do arrive, the productivi­ty gains could be big. Suppose, the authors say, they eliminate the need for two million of the 3.5 million Americans who drive vehicles for a living. That’s 1.7 per cent of private employment in the U. S. If the transition takes place over 10 years, that’s a 0.17 percentage point boost to annual productivi­ty growth: After the decade is over, it will be possible to produce the same total output, all driving included, with 1.7- per- cent fewer people. Similar calculatio­ns for call- centre jobs that could be replaced by increasing­ly sophistica­ted voice- recognitio­n systems ( oh, joy!) add another 0.10 points per year for 10 years.

There are also possibilit­ies for capital productivi­ty growth. If it’s true the average car stands idle 95 per cent of the time, driverless cars will enable much greater efficiency in the use of the car capital stock.

These changes will present obvious difficulti­es for displaced drivers — and maybe even displaced emergency- room doctors, if driving no longer will be subject to human error — and that could well create social problems, even as new jobs do come along. But transforma­tive change at least will explain, and eliminate, this latest version of the productivi­ty paradox.

IT SEEMS LIKELY THE AI REVOLUTION IS GOING THROUGH A LATENT PHASE BEFORE TAKING OFF.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada