National Post

THE TRUMP TAX: 80 BASIS POINTS.

- WILLIAM WATSON

So far the Trump presidency seems to have been good for the U. S. economy. Or at least, given the difficulty of apportioni­ng blame or credit in unique historical events, it hasn’t prevented good economic performanc­e. True, output and employment growth were slower last year than in some Obama years but you’d expect that with the U. S. economy nearing capacity.

So, could there be an economic cost to President Trump? Maybe, says a fun new research paper — fun except for all its econometri­cs — by Barry Eichengree­n, an economic historian at Berkeley, and two colleagues at the European Central Bank, Livia Chitu and Arnaud J. Mehl. The cost they point to is higher interest rates and the mechanism they have in mind is Trump’s possible effect on other countries’ official holdings of U. S. dollars, which run into the trillions.

Many countries don’t reveal the compositio­n of their foreign reserves. Canada does. Our latest numbers show us holding foreign securities and deposits worth almost US$77 billion, with the breakdown being: U.S. dollars, $51 billion; euros, $16 billion; pounds sterling, $8 billion; and Japanese yen, a little less than $1 billion. What determines that breakdown? Is it exchange-rate risk? Trade patterns? Return maximizati­on? Efficient diversific­ation? If economists are managing the money, you’d hope it would be a combinatio­n of all that.

But could it be other things? Internatio­nal politics, say? If we dumped a few billion U. S. dollars to trade for Chinese yuan, do you think we might hear from the Americans, from one D. Trump, in particular? Or are our holdings a result of inertia or even nostalgia? ( How come so many British pounds? Isn’t that a throwback to a time, now long ago, when much of our trade was with Britain?)

Eichengree­n and his colleagues wanted to investigat­e this split between economic and other, mainly geopolitic­al, motives for holding a given combinatio­n of foreign reserves. Unfortunat­ely, the fact that many important countries don’t reveal their holdings made that impossible. So, they did the next best thing. They looked at a historical period for which, thanks to scholarly reconstruc­tion, we do have good data on who held what — namely, the three decades before the First World War.

OK, so a lot has changed between now and 100 years ago. Maybe countries behave completely differentl­y in the 21st century than they did in the late 19th and early 20th. But we economists tend to think human nature doesn’t change much as time goes by so the fundamenta­l things still apply.

In any case, when the three economists related different countries’ century-ago foreign-exchange reserves to standard economic variables they found correlatio­ns strong enough not to be dismissed as random. But when they added variables such as whether countries had formal alliances or extensive diplomatic representa­tion with each other they found that these geopolitic­al considerat­ions also produced correlatio­ns strong enough not to be dismissed as random. So it appears many countries’ holdings are motivated by a mix of economic and political considerat­ions, which on reflection isn’t surprising.

It’s also consistent with what contempora­ry data are available. France, Russia and China, all nuclear powers, have diversifie­d foreign reserves. Germany, Japan and Saudi Arabia, which depend on explicit or implicit American guarantees for their defence, keep their reserves predominan­tly in U. S. dollars. Maybe that’s just an accident. But maybe it isn’t.

Now the fun part. What if, ask the scholars, Trump carries through on his neo- isolationi­st campaign rhetoric and lets allies like South Korea, Japan and Germany take on primary responsibi­lity for their own defence? Getting them to at least share the burden would relieve the United States of US$ 10 billion in annual military expenditur­es, maybe more.

But what if this geopolitic­al re-ordering feeds back into their choices about what assets to hold their foreign reserves in? That would reduce world demand for U.S. dollar assets and, other things equal, raise the interest rates U.S. borrowers have to pay in order to get the rest of the world to hold their debt. The response, if you apply the pre-WWI correlatio­ns, could mean an additional US$ 750 billion flowing out of national reserves and into ordinary debt markets. Standard demand- supply stories about what determines interest rates suggest that to get the world to hold that much more American debt could cost U. S. borrowers an extra 80 basis points. Apply that interest rate hike to total American debt and the hit could be US$ 115 billion a year. By comparison, US$10 billion in military expenditur­es doesn’t look so bad — however objectiona­ble the idea of trading soldiers’ risk for lower interest rates.

The president seemed sweetly reasonable in his State of the Union address Tuesday so maybe he won’t blow up America’s alliances, after all. But if he did, it could have an economic effect this maestro of debt wouldn’t like. Not nice!

WHAT IF GEOPOLITIC­AL RE-ORDERING FEEDS BACK INTO FOREIGN RESERVES?

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada