National Post

Blind bidding isn’t the problem in housing

- PAUL A. JOHNSON

As a student of the dense and specialize­d economic theory of auctions and bidding, I was surprised to see the federal Liberals dive into the topic during the recent election campaign with their “Home Buyers’ Bill of Rights,” which promises to “Ban blind bidding, which prevents bidders from knowing the bids of other prospectiv­e buyers, and ultimately drives up home prices.” The ban wasn’t mentioned in yesterday’s rather brief throne speech but there seems little doubt the government will go ahead with it. Do their claims jibe with the economics of bidding that I was taught in graduate school? After all, as public health and climate crises continue to remind us, good policy should be guided by the received wisdom of specialize­d experts.

The idea of banning blind bidding is certainly an attempt to address current frustratio­ns with housing (un) affordabil­ity. Plus, the proposed ban ties directly to the remorse of home buyers who buy a home with an aggressive bid only to suspect or even learn later that a lower bid would have been accepted.

The first thing that economics tells us about bidding is that different rules result in different bids. If you bought a home with a $1.1 million bid and the next highest bid was $1 million, it’s simply wrong to believe that a ban on blind bidding would have saved you $100,000. Wouldn’t such a ban have given all losing bidders, not just you, an opportunit­y to increase their bids once they learned they were about to lose their dream home? Couldn’t that mean prices might go up even more with a ban on blind bidding?

Recognizin­g that bids change with bidding rules led to the first really important result in bidding theory: the famous revenue equivalenc­e theorem, a contributi­on that was one reason Canadian-born William Vickrey won the 1996 Nobel Prize in economics. One of the first results students of bidding theory learn, the theorem says that bidding rules neither raise nor lower prices paid on average. Sellers can’t use bidding rules to change the fact that price will adjust to equate demand and supply. That baseline economic result certainly provides no basis for claims that banning blind bidding would put a brake on rising home prices.

But because revenue equivalenc­e is a theory, it requires assumption­s. Are those assumption­s realistic in a setting where homes are bought and sold? If not, would more realistic assumption­s give us reasons for optimism? The short answer is no.

Revenue equivalenc­e requires that the value one buyer attaches to an item up for sale is not affected by how much other buyers value that item. That’s not realistic when real estate is being sold: houses can be resold and can also harbour hidden defects. So, if I learn how competing home buyers value the house I’m bidding on, I am reassured that I’m not overestima­ting the home’s value. A more recent economics Nobel Prize was awarded to Stanford University economist Paul Milgrom for studying what happens to bidding in these circumstan­ces. Bidding rules do matter, but a ban on blind bidding, by making bids visible, leads to higher prices. That is the exact opposite of the Liberals’ claim.

To be clear, not all departures from revenue equivalenc­e contradict the Liberals’ claims. In fact, changing other assumption­s can lead to the conclusion that a ban on blind bidding would decrease prices. The point is that the overall effect of a ban is unclear: it depends on the strength of opposing forces that are hard or impossible to estimate. Ultimately, we still have no good theoretica­l basis to expect that a ban on blind bidding would help achieve housing affordabil­ity.

So, taking the bold (but unwise) step of setting theory aside, is there empirical support that a ban on blind bidding would lower home prices? We’ve had no actual experience with such bans in Canada so we can’t look at how Canadian home prices changed after a ban was put in place. But some countries do run their real estate sectors without blind bidding. The University of Ottawa’s Smart Prosperity Institute recently looked at that evidence and concluded that it was, at best, mixed: among countries that don’t use blind bidding, some have seen home prices rise faster than in Canada while others have seen them rise more slowly. That route provides no basis for the Liberals’ claim either.

A stubborn fact of economics is that prices are driven by demand and supply. A ban on blind bidding would do nothing to change those fundamenta­ls. We should not be blind to that fact.

Financial Post Paul A. Johnson holds a PH.D. in economics from Université de Montréal. From 2016-2019, he was chief economist at the Competitio­n Bureau. He currently provides economic consulting services to clients including the Canadian Real Estate Associatio­n.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada