National Post

Stick to facts, not factoids

Let’s stop citing OECD growth forecast

-

Afactoid you hear a lot these days from conservati­ves and Conservati­ves alike is the OECD’S forecast that among all its members Canada will have the slowest economic growth to 2060. That the OECD does forecast this is fact. But conservati­ves, of all people, are usually skeptical of long-term forecasts. They’re certainly skeptical of long-term climate forecasts. They’re also typically skeptical of big internatio­nal organizati­ons. So the forecast itself should be regarded as factoid. It’s therefore interestin­g to see conservati­ves embrace it as if it were gospel according to Adam Smith, Milton Friedman or Ronald Reagan.

The OECD probably is too big, activist and rich, as many conservati­ves believe. But it employs many good economists, gives them great support and has been working on long-term forecastin­g for several years now — partly in response (ironically) to complaints from climate economist William Nordhaus that there are no good long-range economic models to go along with long-range climate models. This is probably because “few scholars or institutio­ns have the temerity to attach numbers to a distant future,” as OECD Policy Paper No 22 (July 2018) puts it before then going ahead and taking a crack at such attachment.

When you hear the OECD has forecast Canada’s economic growth for the next 35 years or so, you think they probably sent a large team here, visited our factories, labs, distributi­on centres, government operations centres and so on and did a critical analysis of what seemed promising, how well we were introducin­g best practices, and so on. But, no, economists do this sort of thing sitting at their computer screens, parsing cross-country data and, what economists do best, making assumption­s.

In general, three things produce output: labour, capital and the know-how with which they’re combined. You get more output over time — your economy grows — if your labour force grows, your capital stock grows or your knowhow grows. Labour force growth is at least somewhat predictabl­e: you can make informed estimates about births and deaths, labour force participat­ion, education rates and so on. You can also make assumption­s about investment rates, and therefore how much your capital/labour ratio grows over time.

Alas, most studies of economic growth find what accounts for it is in the black box: know-how, or, as the OECD terms it, labour efficiency. To forecast labour efficiency the OECD uses a “convergenc­e model.” It assumes countries that are behind in productivi­ty gradually catch up. The farther behind you are, the greater your potential to catch up. Unfortunat­ely (in this regard only!) Canada has high productivi­ty already so is doomed to slower productivi­ty growth than many other countries.

If you look at “trend labour efficiency” in Table 1 of OECD Policy Paper 29 (October 2021), ours is only 0.7 per cent per year for 2030-60 — the same rate as one other country: the U.S., our most common comparator. That our productivi­ty growth has been lagging theirs is one reason the Bank of Canada wants us to break the glass on our productivi­ty emergency. Our having the same forecast productivi­ty growth as they do therefore can’t be terrible news.

True, Europe and the OECD on average are at 0.9 per cent. One reason North America lags is that productivi­ty growth is correlated with trade and the centre of gravity of world trade is shifting to Asia. The OECD estimates the average distance of our trade in 2060 will be 1,750 kilometres longer than now.

Where does labour efficiency grow faster to 2060? Slovakia and Portugal at 1.2 per cent per year. Czechia and Turkey (1.1); Costa Rica, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Korea, Luxembourg, Poland, Slovenia, Spain (1.0), and so on. Small difference­s do compound over time, but so does the influence of small errors in forecastin­g.

We trail the U.S. (and others) in growth of real GDP per capita. Our forecast is 0.8 per cent from 2030-60. The Americans’ is 1.0 per cent. Where does the difference come from? From growth of capital/worker (0.2 per cent for us, 0.3 per cent for them), the share of the population that’s active (-0.2 for us, -0.1 for them); and the potential employment rate (no change for us, growth of 0.1 per cent for them). These are not big difference­s — 0.1 per cent in each case — and some are “natural.” (How much people work is largely a question of age.)

How could we improve? The OECD favours labour market reforms that would get more women into the workforce and persuade more older folk to stay there. But working more hours or years, though it does raise GDP per person, doesn’t necessaril­y raise well-being.

What’s key to that is higher productivi­ty, which OECD working paper 1385 (from 2017, now a little old) looks at. Canada already has the fourth highest levels of education. We’re best for low and stable inflation (or were from 2006-10, the years the study uses). We regulate our product markets, a productivi­ty drag, more than the U.S., U.K. and the Netherland­s (the leaders in this area) but less than the OECD median. Our R&D and patenting numbers aren’t actually bad: 15th and sixth, respective­ly. In terms of income inequality, whose relation to productivi­ty is tenuous, we’re right in the middle of the OECD pack.

Conclusion? It’s all very interestin­g work, very profession­ally done. But policy debates in this country should stick to the facts, not the factoids.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada