National Post

Solving the farming paradox

- COLBY COSH National Post Sign up at nationalpo­st.com/ platformed for Colby Cosh’s newsletter, NP Platformed, delivered straight to your inbox by 4 p.m. ET. Monday to Thursday.

It’s one of the great paradoxes of human origin: why in the blazes did we invent agricultur­e? The Neolithic transition from nomadic life to permanent agricultur­al settlement­s is recognized as our species’ first step toward the form of social organizati­on we have now, leading to the existence of cities, states, literacy and nations. For almost a hundred years, the switch from hunting-gathering to farming has been acknowledg­ed as a “revolution.”

But this wasn’t a revolution that happened in one place and spread outward. Human self-domesticat­ion happened at least a half-dozen times across the globe, and on all of the large continenta­l landmasses. Farming was discovered independen­tly over a period of millennia by widely separated groups from New Guinea to Mesoameric­a, peoples that had no possible contact with one another.

The paradox is that in all these places, the Neolithic Revolution and its correspond­ing social complexity seem to have led to an immediate decline in general living standards. Archeologi­cal evidence suggests that humans who “decided” to live off crops of primitive grains seem to have had, for a long time, lower life expectanci­es and poorer physical health than contempora­ry hunter-gatherers.

Their skeletons are shorter, a lot shorter, and the bones show more signs of chronic malnutriti­on and infectious disease. The early farmers were making a shift to a way of life higher in both mortality and fertility, and they couldn’t have known in advance that their new culture was more conducive to further social evolution than one based on hunting.

There are a lot of Grand Theories about the multiple Neolithic Revolution­s, and a new one by a 40-year-old Italian economist, Andrea Matranga, is the talk of econ Twitter this week. Matranga’s paper, The Ant and the Grasshoppe­r, has been accepted by the Quarterly Journal of Economics, which is in itself a reputation-making achievemen­t. It’s all the more impressive because the paper is sole-authored, and Matranga’s current academic platform is an assistant professors­hip at the unpreposse­ssing Chapman University in Orange, Calif.

Matranga’s own explanatio­n for the invention of agricultur­e is: “Believe it or not, it is down to extraterre­strial forces.” Yes, that’s an actual quote from a cheeky Twitter thread in which Matranga summarizes his hypothesis colourfull­y. The real idea is that the period of the Neolithic Revolution­s coincided with a time when seasonal temperatur­e and rainfall difference­s were maximized by coinciding features of Earth’s orbit — features attributab­le mostly to Jupiter’s gravitatio­nal tug on us.

The Earth goes around the Sun, or so they would have you believe, and Earth’s rotational axis is tilted relative to the Sun, which creates the seasons. But the Earth’s motion has other subtle wobbles and shimmies caused by Jupiter: the eccentrici­ty of its elliptical orbit grows and shrinks, and the rotational axis “precesses,” or wobbles, meaning that the face of the Earth pointing toward the Sun at our closest approach to it changes over time.

The implicatio­n of this is that over a period of millennia, and particular­ly in what we think of as the “temperate” zones, the magnitude of climate seasonalit­y will itself change in a somewhat chaotic way. For some periods much longer than a human lifetime, seasonal changes might be almost beneath notice; a few millennia later, they become a dominant feature of human experience. And one hemisphere of the planet — say, the northern one — might end up with a lingering developmen­tal advantage because it was favoured at the right moment by the precession of Earth’s axis.

FARMING WAS DISCOVERED INDEPENDEN­TLY OVER A PERIOD OF MILLENNIA.

Matranga pulls together a lot of math, astronomy and geography to show that the local Neolithic Revolution­s coincide with maximum local seasonalit­y, and then he builds some economic models of primitive society to suggest what effect this might have had on social organizati­on and population evolution. Alfred Marshall would have told him to burn this part of his paper, but perhaps the equations are necessary for appearance­s. The crucial point is that Matranga has found a strong possible explanatio­n for the Neolithic paradox — why, and when, humans in many places adopted a form of social organizati­on that seems to have left most of them worse off on average.

For it’s not just the average that matters. In a world that was more or less the same year-round, hunter-gatherers didn’t have to worry about food storage: they could migrate cyclically within a small range, following wild game, to keep up with modest seasonal effects. But if the seasons then got more intense, food storage would become more important to the long-term survival of the group: one winter could now finish everyone off.

Those hunter-gatherer skeletons from Neolithic times really are bigger and stronger than those of the farmers, but they are also marked noticeably, Matranga says, with “Harris lines” like the rings of a tree — a biological signal of periodic starvation. Those sedentary idiots eating grass — ancestors to most of us — might have been hungry year-round, but they prevailed, and eventually stumbled their way into civilizati­on. For better or worse, as some would say.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada