National Post (National Edition)

Canada should follow Australia's lead

- JACK M. MINTZ

Every year I receive a federal cheque for the use of my published books by Canadian libraries. The amount, after payment of hefty income taxes, is no more than several months' supply of Tim Hortons coffee. But I do appreciate recognitio­n of the principle that I should be compensate­d for my copyright.

As a “content-provider,” I think of this cheque every time I read about the tussle now taking place between Australia and the massive technology companies, Google and Facebook. Australia is bringing in legislatio­n requiring digital technology companies to compensate news outlets for the use of their content. The legislatio­n is in response to the shift of advertisin­g revenue from broadcaste­rs and publishers to internet platforms that so far have not had to pay the costs of creating content. In response, Facebook has clumsily cut off news informatio­n to Australian­s, raising significan­t concerns about the big tech firms' economic power, not just in Australia but around the world.

Before I jump on the bandwagon accusing Facebook and Google of predatory practices, it must be remembered that the media creating the content can protect its copyright by putting up walls to control access. Broadcasti­ng programs and newspapers can be made available only to those buying a subscripti­on. Although cutting off access in this way does compensate creators for their investment­s, it also both limits the availabili­ty of valuable informatio­n and reduces media advertisin­g revenues, since fewer readers means fewer ad dollars. Without ad revenues, some new outlets might not survive, leading to industry consolidat­ion and, eventually, less content.

A critical issue is how to square two competing goals: providing monetary incentives for content creation while ensuring broad access to that content. This problem was addressed 60 years ago by the late Kenneth Arrow, 1972 Nobelist in economics, in a seminal paper on the economics of invention that still has relevance today.

Informatio­n producers, from pharma companies to book publishers, make returns on their investment­s through patent or copyright protection. This puts them in a “monopoly” position: able to charge a royalty to those wanting to use their unique informatio­n and, as monopolist­s do, potentiall­y limiting use of their product. Like a monopoly, the provider can charge prices above its production costs, restrictin­g the use of informatio­n by the public.

Two benefits have to be balanced. On the one hand, once created, the informatio­n in question could in principle be used by anyone at little, if any cost. As Jefferson wrote: “He who receives an idea from me, receives instructio­n himself without lessening mine; as he who lights his taper at mine, receives light without darkening me.” Universal exploitati­on of a good that everyone could consume at once would obviously be a good thing. On the other hand, if there are no patents or copyrights, creators have less incentive to generate or discover the informatio­n in the first place. This could lead to a worse outcome.

So far, the internet has tilted the balance toward widespread distributi­on of informatio­n, good and bad. While content-providers invest in processes to ensure quality (peer-reviewed refereed academic journals being the strictest), the role of the internet has been to promote communicat­ion, not supervise quality.

What do we do?

Content providers should be compensate­d for the informatio­n they generate while platforms continue their useful role in widespread disseminat­ion. From this perspectiv­e, the Australian­s' attempt to implement mandatory bargaining to protect copyright is in the right direction. Once legislatio­n is in place, the internet platforms and content-creators can negotiate terms around the use of content.

For example, if Google and Facebook want to maximize use of their platforms for advertisin­g revenues, they could pay content-providers to make informatio­n openly accessible to all their users rather than putting up subscripti­on walls.

It might cost the technology companies more, but it makes informatio­n widely available and also maximizes their advertisin­g revenues.

None of this is simple, though. One issue is determinin­g who is a content-provider. Is it every author, organizati­on, publicatio­n or broadcaste­r? For now, the Australian legislatio­n is mainly concerned with the sustainabi­lity and competitiv­eness of news media. Yet it could easily be broadened as other entities lobby for inclusion.

Although Google and Facebook currently have dominant market positions they are not true monopolist­s. Should other companies, like Twitter, LinkedIn and Microsoft, with its Bing search engine, also be required to negotiate contracts?

Perhaps there is an alternativ­e to mandatory bargaining.

As under Canada's program to compensate authors for books used in public libraries, a government could impose a tax on digital advertisin­g, with the revenues transferre­d to content-creators according to some formula. This would give a government the power to disqualify some content-creators for essentiall­y political reasons, however, which would be deeply concerning for free speech and democracy.

On balance, Australia seems to be choosing the best approach to protecting the copyright of content-providers. Some voluntary deals are already being made in Australia and France. But copyright needs to be enforced. Heritage Minister Steven Guilbeault has argued we should follow Australia's approach. He is right.

WITHOUT AD REVENUES, SOME NEW OUTLETS MIGHT NOT SURVIVE.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada