Ottawa Citizen

Firms backing carbon tax may have ulterior motives

NYU PAPER Support could be spurred by ulterior motives

- STUART THOMSON sxthomson@postmedia.com Twitter.com/stuartxtho­mson

When the Alberta government rolled out a carbon tax plan in 2015, the province witnessed a strange sight: Oil company executives flanking premier Rachel Notley as she announced a policy that would cost their companies a ton of money. So, why did they do it? A new paper from New York University economist Amanda Kennard shows that these firms aren’t just lobbying for environmen­tal regulation­s out of the goodness of their corporate hearts: it’s a calculated bet that their competitor­s will be worse off, allowing them to gain an advantage. For example, if a company’s competitor­s are heavily reliant on coal, it will be far more likely to lobby for environmen­tal regulation­s.

The paper also takes aim at the most common explanatio­n for this kind of corporate behaviour: that companies encourage federal lawmakers to harmonize environmen­tal policy across the country to give them certainty and predictabi­lity when it comes to costs. Kennard argues that this just isn’t borne out by the data. In fact, difference­s across various provinces and states could actually benefit certain companies, relative to their competitio­n.

In the paper, Kennard examines the 2009 cap-andtrade legislatio­n passed in the U.S. House of Representa­tives and finds some unlikely supporters of the bill. The aluminum company Alcoa Corporatio­n was a vocal booster of the proposed rules, despite the fact that aluminum smelting is one of the most energy-intensive activities in the world. With about 20 per cent of the company’s costs going towards energy, any emissions legislatio­n would be hugely expensive.

“Alcoa’s support for cap and trade was more than a simple public relations campaign,” writes Kennard. The company was involved in several other environmen­tal initiative­s and engaged in a full-throated lobbying effort to get the bill passed. Why did it do it? One clue came when Alcoa’s direct competitio­n lobbied hard against the bill and publicly threatened to move to Mexico if it passed.

“While climate change policy increases costs across the board, it also leads to shifts in market share, which benefit those firms with relatively low adjustment costs,” writes Kennard. “If these shifts in market share are large, they may compensate for the policy’s direct costs.”

In other words, companies will be happy to pay extra costs provided their competitio­n is hit harder.

Alcoa had a big advantage because it had signed long-term contracts for hydro-electric power for its operations, while the competitio­n was using coal-fired power plants. Although the legislatio­n would still be a cost burden on Alcoa, the cost of adjusting to the new regime was much higher for its domestic competitor­s.

Kennard’s paper also argues that a company’s internatio­nal competitor­s — which may be able to avoid burdensome environmen­tal regulation­s — may not be as big a factor as previously believed. Economists and corporate executives have expressed concerns about this global “carbon leakage,” when onerous environmen­tal rules are imposed. Although most large firms are facing global competitor­s in a world increasing­ly free of trade barriers, most of the lobbying decisions on environmen­tal regulation­s are driven by domestic market share. Those domestic benefits seem to outweigh the global competitio­n.

Kennard outlines three ways that domestic competitor­s could see massively different costs from the same legislatio­n. Cost advantages could come from a company that has invested a lot of money in new, more efficient equipment. Some firms will have access to clean energy and energy-efficient technology. The third factor comes from regional difference­s in electricit­y generation. If an area happens to be coal-intensive, it will end up being more expensive than other regions that rely on cleaner fuel sources.

In a competitiv­e environmen­t, most of these conditions naturally arise.

“Competitio­n between domestic firms is a sufficient condition for supportive lobbying in nearly any regulatory context,” Kennard writes.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada