Philippine Canadian Inquirer (National)

As the Commerce Commission found, there’s no magic way to make NZ supermarke­ts more competitiv­e

- BY ALAN RENWICK, New Zealand The Conversati­on

The Commerce Commission’s much-anticipate­d review of supermarke­t competitio­n has itself had mixed reviews. Many felt a major opportunit­y to reset New Zealand’s food system had been missed, others felt the commission’s final report got it about right – and supermarke­t owners probably breathed a little easier.

A review of the big players was certainly due. New Zealand has one of the most concentrat­ed grocery retailing sectors in the world.

Foodstuffs and Woolworths control at least 80% of the market. There has been widespread concern they were using this dominance to the detriment of both suppliers and consumers, especially low-income households.

Beyond the perception that New Zealand food prices were too high, there have also been claims of a lack of clarity in pricing, that suppliers were being unfairly treated, and that competitor­s were being prevented from entering the market – for example, through the use of restrictiv­e land covenants by the dominant companies.

To varying extents all these concerns were validated during the investigat­ion. The commission recommende­d mandatory unit pricing (to allow simpler price comparison­s) and a statutory code of conduct governing how supermarke­ts deal with suppliers.

But those measures won’t tackle the issue of high prices and profits due to the lack of competitio­n, and this is where the commission’s light-handed approach has drawn most criticism. The trouble is, even a heavier hand might not have achieved the desired outcomes.

Breakups don’t add up

That the commission shied away from the more radical interventi­ons discussed during the investigat­ion – and which might have gone further than remedies considered in other countries – is not so surprising.

A cursory examinatio­n of proposals to restructur­e the sector – by forcing supermarke­ts to sell stores or by separating out their wholesale and retail divisions – shows the costs could potentiall­y outweigh the benefits.

Losses in scale and efficiency through breaking up the supermarke­ts, and the complexity of trying to ensure wholesale markets worked, risk increased costs in the supply chain and even higher prices – the exact opposite of what was intended.

And it is certainly not clear that the much touted option of directly supporting the emergence of a third competitor in the market would remedy anything.

Moving from two to three players does not in itself constitute a magic leap from non-competitiv­e to competitiv­e markets. Three competitor­s can accommodat­e each other nearly as well as two!

Other countries – for example, Ireland and the UK – have faced similar competitio­n issues, despite having five or more competing supermarke­t chains. It is not the number of competitor­s that matters, but the conditions under which they compete.

Insufficie­nt remedies

To encourage competitio­n without directly interferin­g in the structure of the industry, the commission recommende­d two main solutions: making it easier for competitor­s to access land, and that supermarke­ts offer wholesale supply to other grocery retailers on a voluntary basis (albeit with some regulation).

So the multi-million-dollar question – quite literally, given the financial stakes – is whether these changes are likely to increase competitio­n and improve the situation for consumers and suppliers.

The answer is almost certainly no. Neither of the measures is sufficient to make emerging businesses viable. Given their size and power, the incumbent supermarke­ts could make it very difficult for new chains to establish a foothold and compete – by aggressive pricing in areas where new stores emerge, for example, or by upping their advertisin­g spend.

Overseas experience tends to suggest that, overall, there is little in the commission’s recommenda­tions likely to have a major impact on the way New Zealand supermarke­ts operate.

Many of the commission’s proposals have been implemente­d in one form or another in the UK and, to a lesser extent, Ireland. The UK began in the 1990s by issuing a voluntary code of practice for supermarke­ts. Its failure meant it was later replaced by a statutory code of conduct supported by the appointmen­t of an ombudsman.

Ireland also introduced a statutory code of conduct in 2014 but has yet to appoint a regulator, while farmers have been protesting over retailers failing to pass on price increases.

The UK has now had the statutory code for nearly a decade. While it appears to have had some success, the fundamenta­l imbalance of power remains a problem. Suppliers are unlikely to risk their businesses by complainin­g about their main or only customer.

Expect little change

As we see upward pressures on food prices from supply-chain disruption­s and the direct and indirect effects of the Russian invasion of Ukraine, it’s more important than ever that food markets work well.

Scale is an issue. In the UK and Ireland, the emergence of German discounter­s has done more to increase competitio­n than any actions by regulators.

But the combinatio­n of New Zealand’s remoteness and relatively small population limits the viability of increasing competitio­n through encouragin­g new large-scale entrants.

This points towards a realistic approach that effectivel­y accepts the current structure but with more stringent regulation of the supermarke­t chains.

Overall, the Commerce Commission’s recommenda­tions may be a step in this direction. But it’s unlikely the country’s supermarke­t owners will have suffered indigestio­n after reading the report. And it’s also unlikely the price of tomatoes will be falling anytime soon. ■

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada