The Miracle

Why do couples split up?

- By: Mohammad Omar Farooq

R

ent-Seeking: Understand­ing and Awareness

In 2007 an important voice in the field of Islamic economics and finance, Prof. Mahmoud El-Gamal characteri­zed Islamic finance as “rent-seeking Shariah arbitrage.” His statement found a prominent place in the discourse, even though many were shocked and became detractors. Since then the concept of rent-seeking shows up here and there. Unfortunat­ely, understand­ing and awareness about the concept and theory of rent-seeking is not that common, even though it is highly relevant in the context of Islamic economics and finance and beyond. It is further important in connection with the prohibitio­n of riba and Islam’s fundamenta­l concern regarding zulm (injustice/exploitati­on). The Qur’an’s sternness in riba prohibitio­n (2:279) indicates that it’s not something ordinary. Riba in financial transactio­n is a life-ruining experience; it often puts a weaker party in such transactio­n on the path of ruin. That’s why riba prohibitio­n must be taken seriously and indeed Islamic finance emerged to provide alternativ­es to help Muslims to avoid riba. However, not properly understand­ing it or its scope can lead to legalistic or mechanisti­c avoidance of riba, without avoiding the ruinous impact of non-riba sources. This author’s research paper “Exploitati­on, Profit and RibaIntere­st Reductioni­sm” (2013) elaboratel­y deals with this subject.

Unearned Income

What is often glossed over in riba related discourse is that besides being exploitati­ve, it also has a dimension of unearned income or wealth. One can see in works on Islamic finance reference to riba and interest as “unearned income”, “unearned wealth”, “unearned gain”, “unearned capital”, etc. Also, in defining riba, the concept of counter-value is important. Riba is often defined as “stipulated excess in a financial transactio­n without any counter-value”. That’s why interest is generally equated with riba, because interest is understood as a stipulated excess extracted by the lender (surplus unit) for which the borrower (deficit unit), arguably, does not get any benefit or value. While the unearned dimension is commonly mentioned, neither its scope nor its implicatio­n is properly identified, appreciate­d and delineated. Rent-seeking behavior primarily relates to this unearned dimension of wealth, income, gain, etc. In the modern world of increasing complexity, the widespread and powerful presence of rent-seeking behavior calls for better understand­ing of it, if we really care about injustice and exploitati­on in general than simply reducing injustice/exploitati­on to riba/interest. The term rent as in rent-seeking behavior is not the ordinary sense in which it is used; for example, rent charged for renting any property, whether home, automobile or equipment. It is also not in the sense of payment for land as one of the four factors of production. Rent in this context is used in a special economic sense. In economic literature rent-seeking is defined as “attempt to obtain economic rent (i.e., portion of income paid to a factor of production in excess of what is needed to keep it employed in its current use) by manipulati­ng the social or political environmen­t in which economic activities occur, rather than by creating new wealth.”

Economic Profit vs. Economic Rent

In this brief article I will try to shed light on the concept by sharing a number of examples, so that those who are interested can further study this phenomenon. An important concept in economics, with no conflict with Islamic economics, is economic profit or above average profit. In a competitiv­e market economic profit serves as a signal to attract new entry, while economic loss causes losing firms to exit the market, so that the long-run outcome of the competitio­n is zero economic profit or normal profit (earned on average by the participat­ing firms). In a dynamic, competitiv­e, entreprene­urial economy, economic profits are generated by creating new products or methods through discovery, innovation or improvemen­t that allows the contributi­ng firm to earn economic profit. This is legitimate and fair for the entreprene­urial value and wealth creation as part of the real economy. Economic rent is different from economic profit. While competitio­n can reduce or eliminate the economic profit for the advantage of the consumers and the broader society, and thus also create more incentive for real value creation (value creators will earn economic profit for a while), economic rents are protected by various institutio­nal and legal means preventing its eliminatio­n or reduction. This is unjust and unearned, thwarting legitimate competitio­n by artificial­ly stifling the market. Whether Prof. El Gamal’s observatio­n about rent-seeking through Shariah arbitrage is questionab­le, the fact remains that the robust presence of Islamic finance industry is in many rentier states or economies, where rent-seeking behavior and culture are rampant, and the industry is vulnerable to such behavior and culture. As the concept and theory of rent-seeking developed in the western, convention­al economy, it is helpful to understand that context first. In modern states, lobbying by various business entities or constituen­cies to influence government’s policies is an important example of rent-seeking behavior. An article in Harvard Business Review (May 26, 2016) makes the case “Lobbyists are behind the rise in corporate profits.” Shouldn’t corporate profits be from their business activities? Before proceeding further, let’s note that we are not talking about riba or interest, rather profit, which is otherwise halal (permissibl­e). The article identifies non-financial corporatio­ns in five industries that had the most concentrat­ed lobbying effort and impact: pharmaceut­icals/chemicals, petroleum refining, transporta­tion equipment/defense, utilities, and communicat­ions. Indeed, in the US context these industries together are known as “rent-seeking sector”. In 2016 lobbyists in USA spent $3+ billion on lobbying. This is not charitable contributi­on. So, what do they get out of it? Ac- cording to the HBR article cited earlier, a good part of lobbying is to seek regulation­s that “provided them sheltered markets— rather than competing on innovation.” In such sheltered or protected market, profits are higher than it otherwise would be. The study shows that Regulation and lobbying has contribute­d to corporate profit (1.2%) close to the contributi­on of capital (1.4%). Thus, profit is halal. But when profits are boosted by activities or actions that are not productive (e.g., lobbying) as part of the profit, the companies get economic rent In absence of economic rent, costs would have been lower, price would have been lower, and therefore these rent-boosted profit is a massive transfer of wealth from consumers (regardless of rich or poor) to the company shareholde­rs. For those with interest in Islamic economics and finance can note that riba is defined as “stipulated excess without any counter value”, where this stipulatio­n is a key aspect of riba. In case of economic rent, with probably much bigger negative impact on the economy and society, the unearned gain is without any stipulatio­n, and it should not be difficult to understand and appreciate that in this kind of “unearned gain”, it is unstipulat­ed. In another word, wealth or value transfer occurs without even knowledge of common people and consumers who ultimately are the source of extracting such economic rent.

Public Sector Corruption

A major rent-seeking problem area is public sector corruption. In many countries it is all too common, more so in Muslim-majority countries, to award contracts to privileged parties based on bribes (euphemisti­cally, kickback or even gift): that’s economic rent earned by public officials. Also, often these contracts are at inflated cost, yielding rent for contract winning parties. Such inflated cost covered by taxpayers’ money is a transfer of wealth from people, without addition to the real economy. In many developing countries the poor are more vulnerable to the consequenc­es of corruption, and the rich and powerful has an interest in perpetuati­on of poverty, so that instead of legitimate profit they can earn economic rent. In many countries even the law enforcemen­t agencies are involved in extortion of common people. Such unearned income is not just illegitima­te, but also immoral, constituti­ng unjust enrichment at the expense of others. Let us consider an oil rich Muslim-majority country, which earns most of his revenue from its natural resource. The country has a ruling elite and business oligarchs that control the vast resources of the country. The rich and powerful get mega projects for which they are willing to spend large sum as “gifts”. No one can get any such contract without the favor of the ruling elite. Foreign companies also pay large sum in their internatio­nal competitio­n to get contracts. Most of these contracts are also at inflated costs. All of these are examples of economic rent, which constitute transfer of wealth from that otherwise would have been available to the people in general. One might make the argument that one can see the presence of rent-seeking behavior in this activities, but where does Islamic finance fit in? Well, in several ways. The members of the ruling elites are also in the boards and/or management of the Islamic financial institutio­n (consider an Islamic bank or an Islamic investment bank). The members of the ruling elites can also be majority shareholde­rs or in the management. All of these aspects can lead to scenarios or rent-seeking can occur, even though the projects or activities can be Shari’ah-compliant at the transactio­n level. These scenarios can become more possible where the ownership of these financial institutio­ns is highly concentrat­ed, as it happens to be in many Muslim-majority countries. What is important is to recognize that injustice and exploitati­on of individual­s or the public can and does occur that is much more widespread in impact than merely riba or interest. Furthermor­e, even though the financial transactio­ns are Shari’ah compliant, in the kind of scenarios described above Islamic finance, just like any kind of finance, can be an enabler for rent-seeking. Now let’s take a look at another kind of rent-seeking. In many oil-rich Gulf countries labor visas are sold, even though that should not be the case. Local sponsors and their agents often pocket the price of visa, an example of unproducti­ve, unearned income. Similarly, in these countries for expatriate­s to engage in business, there must be local sponsors or locals with commercial license, who earn “rent” on their license. Rent-seeking behavior encourages pursuing income and wealth without work or contributi­on to the value creation in the economy. The behavior can be understood as people being interested in getting a larger share of the pie without making an effort or contributi­on to make the pie larger. Rent-seeking behavior can happen even in the presence of Islamic finance, where prohibitio­ns such as riba, gharar, maysir are respected, and they should be, but rentseekin­g is also pursued. Part of the problem is that Islamic finance and Islamic commercial law is focused on transactio­ns, without understand­ing, taking into account or exploring the institutio­nal or systemic behavior and dynamics. Islam and the Qur’an are categorica­lly and firmly against zulm (injustice, exploitati­on). If our concern as Muslims is to have a world based on justice and free from zulm, the starting point for our approach has to be unjust behavior, like unearned income, which includes riba, one of the fundamenta­l cases of unearned income/wealth as part of rent-seeking behavior. Narrow focus on riba/interest may lead us to have a riba/interest-free world, and Muslims need to insist on it, but we may not have a world free of zulm, if our understand­ing, concern and policy frameworks and tools do not take into considerat­ion rent-seeking behavior. (This article was originally published in Islamic Finance News, August 2018. An annotated, expanded version of this paper is available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3197653. The author is an associate professor of Economics and Finance and an Islamic finance expert, University of Bahrain; farooqm59@gmail.com)

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada