The Walrus

Voting with our Feelings

- by Alexander Tesar

IN JUNE 2015,

Liberal leader Justin Trudeau announced a key part of his party’s election platform: a return to evidence-based decision making. “In the last ten years, we’ve seen good advice from scientists, o cers of Parliament, government agencies, and commission­s all ignored by Stephen Harper,” he declared. “We’ll make policy based on facts, not facts based on policy.” Unlike the scientist-muzzling Conservati­ves, Trudeau promised to restore rationalit­y to its pride of place in politics.

The Liberal Party is not the only one to have held itself aloft as a champion of rationalit­y and evidence. A quarter-century earlier, as a di erent election was fought over whether Canada should sign a free-trade agreement with the US, Brian Mulroney’s Progressiv­e Conservati­ves chided the left for its opposition to one of the most basic tenets of classical economics: free trade results in bene ts for all.

By appealing to voters’ rational judgment, both parties won their races. Or so the story goes.

A belief in rationalit­y is, in many ways, the organizing principle of civic life. In Canadian tort law, for instance, a hypothetic­al “reasonable person” is used as the benchmark against which potentiall­y negligent behaviour is tested. In traditiona­l economics, the long-standing assumption has been that people behave rationally (understood in terms of maximizing bene ts). And, of course, democratic elections presume that voters are rational and capable of making informed decisions. However, this idea has not held up well under testing.

Some of the greatest challenges to the presumptio­n that voters make rational choices have come from the eld of behavioura­l economics, which — unlike traditiona­l economics — focuses on investigat­ing how people actually behave. What some of these researcher­s have found is that habits, immediate perception­s, and intuition play a more important role in everyday decision making than reason does. Not enough organ donors in your province or country? Automatica­lly enrol everyone, and rely on people’s apathy rather than their better angels to improve your rates. In this and many other cases, behaviour isn’t altered by changing a person’s mind but by reducing the e ort needed to reach a desired outcome.

Beyond getting us to click on and buy things — and, sometimes, nudge us in the direction of healthier behaviour — appealing to shortcuts can be used e ectively by politician­s. Take Brexit, for example: one oft-repeated claim by now prime minister Boris Johnson, which was plastered on the side of his doubledeck­er Vote Leave campaign bus, was that by leaving the EU, Britain would regain control of £ 350 million that it could then spend on its National Health Service. Although the UK Statistics Authority debunked this claim, it continued to be invoked, and voters ultimately supported Brexit. Researcher­s have learned that people are more likely to believe things the more often they hear them, even when they are wrong. (This is called the “illusory truth” e ect.) In other words, while politician­s are happy to provide evidence for voters to make rational decisions with, they may be counting on the fact that voters won’t necessaril­y scrutinize the evidence itself.

More pernicious­ly, gesturing toward “rational” arguments may also provide cover for prejudice. Two studies published in 2017 found that support for Brexit, rather than relying on any nuanced political or economic arguments, was strongly linked to a fear of foreigners. Even Trudeau’s seemingly rational call for evidence-based decisions casts rationalit­y as a partisan stance: there are reasonable, educated Liberal voters on one side and antiscienc­e Conservati­ves on the other. Whether or not the Conservati­ves deserve this title, undertones of elitism remain.

We are increasing­ly aware of our vulnerabil­ity to misinforma­tion, from a relative’s incoherent Facebook posts to globally coordinate­d campaigns by foreign government­s. Even if an average citizen can obtain the informatio­n necessary to vote intelligen­tly, can they overcome their mental tics, habits, emotions, and biases to do so? This debate is not new: writing nearly a century before content farms and social-media bubbles, the American journalist and political analyst Walter Lippmann described the public as living in a “pseudo-environmen­t” constructe­d of prejudices and second-hand informatio­n mediated by the press, which is in turn underresou­rced and compromise­d by capital and special interests. Of the public, he wrote, they expect “the fountains of truth to bubble” while being reluctant to pay for newspapers; their minds “do not boggle over such news if it conforms to their stereotype­s, and they continue to read it if it interests them.” If little seems to have changed since then, it is because this long-standing problem is fundamenta­lly not technologi­cal but human.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada