Vancouver Sun

TAX me like a SWEDE

How Scandinavi­an- style ‘ dual- income tax’ could cure Canada’s competitiv­e woes

- Jack Mintz Jack M. Mintz is the Palmer Chairman, School of Public Policy, University of Calgary.

We often think about the two sure things in life — death and taxes — but a third is the continuing refrain about Canada’s poor productivi­ty or output produced by workers. When it comes to tax reform and its potential impact on productivi­ty, Canada has not been complacent in the past two decades. These reforms have helped boost incomes since 2000 with better trade performanc­e and lower unemployme­nt.

We have adopted the GST and HST to replace uncompetit­ive federal and provincial sales taxes in most provinces that have encouraged trade and capital investment. Business taxes have been reduced with much lower corporate rates and the eliminatio­n of most capital taxes. Federal and provincial government­s have also cut marginal personal tax rates, including the top rate from more than 53% in 1991 to 46% in 2012 ( except for the recent Ontario rate hike by 2013 to more than 49% from 46.4% for incomes more than $ 500,000).

Nonetheles­s, growth in output per worker has performed inadequate­ly. A recent Statistics Canada report shows Canada’s growth in output per worker still lags the United States and has slowed down during the past decade. Have these past tax reforms failed?

In terms of capital spending, our improved tax system has helped. Tangible investment in machinery and structures grew more quickly in the 2000- 2008 period ( 5% per year) compared to the previous quarter century ( 3.8% per year). Intangible capital has also increased in part due to tax preference­s for research, exploratio­n and marketing. Canadian businesses spent $ 40- billion in 1990 on tax- favoured intangible capital, representi­ng 8.6% of GDP. By 2008, these investment­s grew to $ 150- billion ( 13.2% of GDP) even though more growth took place in the IT- dominated decade of the 1990s.

Despite the growth, we continue to lag our U. S. counterpar­ts, which ultimately means we must find new taxation measures to spur growth and entreprene­urship.

Our tax system is non- neutral, distorting investment decisions and organizati­onal choices. It is typically geared to supporting businesses with poor economic performanc­e while imposing much higher penalties on those that perform well. Entreprene­urs taking on risky, innovative investment­s see the hand of government taking almost a 50% share of profits but little share of potential losses. Further, Canada is laden with many small businesses that typically fail to grow in part because many would lose the many special tax concession­s upon which they rely.

In recent years, many countries have moved to tax bases that reduce or eliminate personal and corporate taxes on capital income. One approach is to adopt expenditur­e bases for personal and corporate taxation by enabling investors and businesses to deduct investment­s from their income and fully tax the disposal of assets. Another is to shift broadbase sales taxes like the valueadded tax. Belgium and Italy have recently adopted “rent- based” corporate taxes that fully deduct investment costs from profits.

If Canada were to adopt a full-expenditur­e tax for personal and corporate taxes, it would remove limits for investment­s in RRSPS and TFSAS, as well as allow businesses to expense rather than depreciate capital expenditur­es. Interest expense incurred by individual­s and businesses to finance capital expenditur­es would no longer be permitted.

In general, the expenditur­e approach to taxation would cost a lot of revenue. Government­s would either need to cut spending or increase other taxes or user fees.

Another approach is a compromise. In recent years, Scandinavi­an and some other European economies have converted their corporate and personal taxes into a “dual- income tax” with low, flat tax rates on capital income ( dividends, interest, capital gains and corporate income) with a progressiv­e rate on wages and salaries. Sweden, being the first, adopted the dual- income tax to encourage capital investment­s and growth after the 1990 recession, as well as reduce tax preference­s for some types of investment, especially housing, since mortgage interest is deductible.

The Scandinavi­an dual- income tax could be an appealing approach for personal and corporate taxation for Canada. For example, if the federal- provincial capital income tax rate were about 15% on dividends, capital gains and interest, tax rates would sharply fall from existing average federalpro­vincial rates ( 23% for capital gains, roughly 30% on dividends and 46% on interest, ignoring Ontario’s recent surtax on the rich).

Small and large businesses would be taxed at the same rate, removing the taxation wall that impedes their growth. If government­s also avoid their predilecti­on to interfere with business decisions and remove tax preference­s for certain business activities, the tax system should also help contribute to better productivi­ty.

From the perspectiv­e of entreprene­urship, the dual- income tax would sharply reduce tax on capital income on investors. It would enable entreprene­urs to keep more of their gains from risky investment­s and encourage business growth. It would also enable Canadians to earn a higher net yield from their investment­s and help restore lost retirement wealth given the state of the stock market in recent years.

If expenditur­e or dual- income taxes do not provide better tax policy for productivi­ty and growth, I don’t know what will.

 ?? PAWEL KOPCZYNSKI / REUTERS FILES ?? Sweden adopted a dual- income tax system, which allows for low, flat tax rates on capital income,
to encourage capital investment­s and growth after the 1990 recession.
PAWEL KOPCZYNSKI / REUTERS FILES Sweden adopted a dual- income tax system, which allows for low, flat tax rates on capital income, to encourage capital investment­s and growth after the 1990 recession.
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada