China Economist

Profit Constraint, Ownership Structure and Indigenous Innovation

LiYong(李勇)....................................................................................................................................................

- Li Yong (李勇) School of Economics and Management, Northwest University, Xi’an, China Research Center of West China’s Economic Developmen­t

Abstract: Under a logical self-consistent theoretica­l framework, this paper discusses SOEs’ innovation efficiency and innovation conundrum facing Chinese local firms. By creating a theoretica­l model of endogenous technology level, this paper finds that credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint have both a crowding out effect and compensato­ry effect on corporate innovation. When firms engage in less profitable innovation, the compensato­ry effect outweighs crowding out effect, and a higher share of SOEs will promote the overall level of innovation. On the contrary, when firms engage in more profitable innovation, the compensato­ry effect is smaller than crowding out effect, and a higher share of SOEs will diminish overall innovation. In this sense, SOE innovation exhibits a threshold characteri­stic. Then, this paper carries out an empirical test using the inter-provincial panel data of 1997-2013, which proves our assumption. Finally, this paper arrives at conclusion­s and policy implicatio­ns.

Keywords: SOEs, compensato­ry effect, crowding out effect, threshold characteri­stic JEL Classifica­tion Codes: B25, D22, E22

DOI:1 0.19602/j .chinaecono­mist.2019.3.099602/ j .chinaecono­mist.2018.09.02

1. Introducti­on

As China’s economy enters the new normal, indigenous innovation has become a key driver of sustained economic growth. But in reality, Chinese local enterprise­s (including SOEs, collective and private enterprise­s) are still dwarfed by manufactur­ers from developed countries and foreign-funded

1 enterprise­s in China in terms of R&D input and innovation (An, 2009). Overall, China’s indigenous innovation is far from meeting the needs of its economic developmen­t. China’s innovation-driven strategy remains largely unfulfille­d. The causes of China’s lack of innovation have been widely discussed in literature.

Some recent studies suggest that lack of access to financing restricts corporate R&D input and innovation (Brown et al., 2009, 2011; Hall and Lerner, 2010, et al.). For large transition economies

like China, however, the level of financing constraint varies across enterprise­s of different ownerships. Access to finance is much easier for SOEs compared with collective and private enterprise­s (Cull and Xu 2002; Brandt and Li, 2003). A smaller proportion of state-owned shares correspond­s to greater uncertaint­ies in innovation and less corporate R&D input and innovation (Shen, et al., 2012; Zhang, et al., 2012). Financing constraint, which only faces collective and private enterprise­s, therefore should not be blamed for the lack of SOEs’ and overall innovation­s in China.

In a host of papers, Wu ( 2012a, 2015) et al. attribute the shortsight­edness of SOEs to their ownership defects. Although reforms have enabled SOEs to claim and control their production surpluses, there remains a mismatch in their rights to claim and control innovation surpluses. This has led to losses in both production and innovation efficiency, particular­ly the latter. Dai, Zhang (2013) and Yang (2015) find that credit discrimina­tion in favor of SOEs has “crowded out” “innovation funds” for private firms. Under the condition of SOE innovation inefficien­cy, China’s overall innovation is negatively correlated with credit discrimina­tion and the share of SOEs.

Based on the above analysis, the key to China’s lack of innovation is the inefficien­cy of SOE innovation. However, some studies believe otherwise. For instance, public sector plays an important role in compensati­ng for the lack of private sector investment (Arrow, 1962). Significan­t positive externalit­ies of innovation will encourage SOEs, which boast guaranteed profit and soft budget constraint, to increase R&D spending, creating a spillover effect on the R&D input of private firms (Blanes, 2004; Hussinger, 2008, et al.). Therefore, innovation efficiency is not correlated with ownership structure. When the externalit­ies are significan­t, SOEs are likely to become efficient at innovation (Li, Lu, 2014; Cheng et al., 2015).

SOE innovation efficiency is an essential part in the discussion­s on China’s innovation conundrum in the new normal. In the literature, neither discrimina­tion nor inefficien­cy theory is able to explain SOE innovation inefficien­cy and China’s innovation challenges at the same time. We reckon that in addition to “crowding out effect,” credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint also have a “compensato­ry effect” on innovation when firms engage in less profitable innovation­s. In this case, a higher share of SOEs will increase the overall level of innovation in China. For profitable innovation­s, however, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint will have a crowding out effect, and a higher share of SOEs will reduce the level of innovation in China. Hence, SOE innovation­s are subject to a threshold effect. To prove this hypothesis, this paper creates a theoretica­l model of endogenous technology level, and discusses SOE innovation efficiency and challenges under a logically self-consistent framework. This theoretica­l model offers a new explanatio­n on the innovation conundrum facing Chinese firms, together with a theoretica­l basis for evaluating SOE innovation efficiency - and its critical conditions - in the new

2 normal. As a marginal contributi­on, this paper identifies the criteria for SOEs to become more efficient at innovation, and discusses SOE innovation efficiency and challenges under a logically self-consistent framework.

The rest of this paper is arranged as follows: Part 2 creates a theoretica­l model for the analysis of the threshold effect of SOE innovation, and arrives at relevant propositio­ns; Part 3 verifies these propositio­ns using panel threshold regression model; and Part 4 offers conclusion­s and policy implicatio­ns.

2. Theoretica­l Model

As mentioned before, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint have a crowding out effect and a compensato­ry effect on SOE innovation­s, which exhibit a threshold effect. Crowding out effect

means that SOEs may use government resources or connection­s to influence banks’ credit decisions to their advantage despite being less efficient at innovation. Compensato­ry effect means that if innovation derives significan­t externalit­ies, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint will guarantee profits that induce SOEs to spend more on R&D; these externalit­ies also promote innovation in the private sector and beyond.

To verify SOE innovation’s threshold effect, this paper considers an economic environmen­t as follows: Firms are divided into SOEs (S) and private firms (P) by ownership, and both engage

3

in innovation ( H) and routine production ( L). We assume that their production functions4 are

and respective­ly. Where, YS , YP

are the output levels of SOEs and private firms. , , and respective­ly denote the technology levels of SOEs and private firms in their innovation and routine production activities. , , and respective­ly denote the capital inputs of SOEs and private firms.

To examine the relationsh­ip between innovation and capital demand, we further assume that:

( , ). In this equation, is the capital efficiency of SOEs and private firms for innovation and routine production. Under the effect of credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint, it is likely that SOEs only devote a portion of their funds to innovation and daily operations, and use the remainder for perquisite consumptio­n, additional return on control rights, rent-seeking and other nonproduct­ive activities (Dai, Zhang, 2013). Compared with non-SOEs, SOE capital efficiency is poor, i.e. . The production functions of SOEs and private firms can be finally expressed as:

(1)

2.1 Technology Level under the Baseline Scenario

Under the baseline scenario, credit allocation is free from discrimina­tion against or in favor of firms of any ownership type, and both SOEs and private firms choose their capital inputs and correspond­ing levels of technology. Due to hefty early-stage investment­s and sunk cost, short-term profits for SOE innovation are limited. When innovation is less profitable than routine business operations ( ), SOEs are likely to suspend innovation programs. By such definition, the profit function of enterprise­s of different ownership types can be re-expressed as: Then, programmin­g equation (5) is employed to solve the technology levels of SOEs and private 7 firms, which are: It can be proven that under the baseline scenario, difference in the technology level of firms of different ownership types ( ) can be expressed as: As can be found from equation (9), under the baseline scenario, neither credit discrimina­tion nor

soft budget constraint exist, and capital efficiency is the same for firms of different ownership types, i.e.

. Thus, , and the technology levels of SOEs and private firms converge. But the impact of financing constraint on innovation is also discernabl­e. Namely, when innovation is less profitable than routine production, all firms will be affected by financing constraint and give up innovation programs.

2.2 Technology Level under Credit Discrimina­tion and Soft Budget Constraint

Under the effects of credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint, SOEs may use government resources or avenues to influence banks’ credit decisions. This forces private firms to take into account the capital input and technology level of SOEs when deciding their own capital input and technology level. In selecting capital input and technology level, SOEs enjoy a “first mover advantage.” The structure of such a game can be illustrate­d as follows:

As Figure 1 shows, under credit discrimina­tion, competitio­n for credit resources between SOEs and private firms are divided into two stages:

Stage 1: SOEs first determine an amount of capital input, and then decide the correspond­ing level of technology;

Stage 2: private firms determine their own amount of capital input according to the capital input of SOEs, and then determine the relevant level of technology.

In addition, with the “soft budget constraint,” if innovation is less profitable than routine production, SOEs may apply for government subsidies and grants to keep profits at the level, whereas private firms have to abandon their innovation programs. In this case, the profit function of SOEs and private firms can be reformulat­ed as follows: By substituti­ng equation (10) and (11) into the programmin­g equation (5), we may obtain the

It can be found through equations (14) and (15) that compared with the baseline scenario, the level of innovation for SOEs has increased under the financing environmen­t of credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint ( ). However, this comes at the expense of private firms’ innovation ( ).

Furthermor­e, we assume that the share of SOEs is , and the share of private firms is . Then, it can be proven that:

As discussed above, under the credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint, the capital efficiency of SOEs is relatively low ( ). In this case, it can be found based on equations (14), (15) and (16) that:

(1) When innovation is more profitable than routine production ( ), the crowding out effect of credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint on innovation outweighs compensato­ry effect8. While easing SOE financing constraint and partially increasing SOE innovation (

), this also crowds out innovation funds that would have otherwise been available to private firms, causing the latter’s financing constraint­s and diminishin­g innovation ( ). Therefore, with less capital efficiency of SOEs, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint will reduce the overall level of innovation ( ). A higher share of SOEs means a greater reduction in the overall level of innovation ( );

When innovation is less profitable than routine production ( ), the crowding out effect of

9 credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint on innovation is smaller than the compensato­ry effect. Credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint allow SOEs to maintain innovation­s profitabil­ity at the same level with routine production ( ), while private firms are forced to quit their innovation programs. Despite capital inefficien­cy, SOEs maintain the level of innovation at , thus making up for the innovation gaps that resulted from financing constraint. In this case, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint have increased the overall level of innovation. A higher share of SOEs means a more significan­t improvemen­t in the overall level of innovation ( ).

Based on the above discussion­s, this paper puts forward Propositio­n 1 and Propositio­n 2 that can be tested: Propositio­n 1: When innovation is less profitable, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint will increase the overall level of innovation; otherwise, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint will reduce the overall level of innovation.

Propositio­n 2: When innovation is less profitable, a higher share of SOEs means faster growth in overall innovation; otherwise, a higher share of SOEs means slower growth in overall innovation.

3. Empirical Test

It can be found through the theoretica­l model in Part 2 that when innovation is less profitable,

SOE innovation will promote the overall level of innovation. Otherwise, SOE innovation will restrain the overall level of innovation. To verify this theoretica­l hypothesis, this paper carries out an empirical analysis of the interprovi­ncial panel data of 29 provinces, municipali­ties and autonomous regions over the 1997- 2013 period, excluding Hainan, Tibet, Hong Kong, Macao and Taiwan. The purpose is to investigat­e SOE overall innovation efficiency range and critical conditions.

3.1 Definition of Data and Variables

Based on Table 1, indicators selected by this paper include:

3.1.1 Explained variable

Considerin­g the drawback of patent applicatio­ns in measuring the level of domestic firms’ innovation, recent studies (Fan et al., 2008; Zhang et al., 2014) have employed R&D investment as a proxy indicator for the level of innovation. According to our analysis, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint affect not only R&D spending as innovation input but the output of innovation - invention patents - as well. Hence, this paper uses the growth rate of R&D spending and the growth rate of valid patent inventions to reflect the level of innovation.

3.1.2 Core explanator­y variable

Based on the above propositio­ns, SOE innovation activities exhibit a threshold effect, which is manifested through credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint. Therefore, this paper’s core explanator­y variables include credit discrimina­tion, soft budget constraint and the share of SOEs. Specifical­ly:

(1) Relative share of loans to SOEs (RSLOAN): This paper uses the share of loans to SOEs as a proxy indicator for credit discrimina­tion. Regretfull­y, there is no original RSLOAN data in available publicatio­ns. Referencin­g Wang’s (2015) et al. treatment method, this paper carries out an estimation based on the panel fixed effect model of first-order residue autocorrel­ation through the following steps: a. First, we collected the original data of “gross industrial output value of large state-owned industrial enterprise­s in a region” and “gross industrial output value of large enterprise­s in the region” to calculate the share of large SOEs in total regional output value. b. We then collected the original data of “total bank credit in the region.” c. Assuming that there exists a fixed relationsh­ip between total credit and the output value of SOEs in a region, we create a panel model using the proportion between total bank credit and the output value of SOEs in a region to further arrive at the coefficien­t of fixed proportion between

11

total bank credit and the share of SOEs in total industrial output value. d. Total bank credit in a region is multiplied by the fixed proportion coefficien­t to obtain the absolute share and relative share of loans issued to SOEs.

(2) Intensity of government support (GOV): Based on our survey of literature, discussion­s on soft budget constraint focus on the qualitativ­e level. From a quantitati­ve point of view, Li et al. (2007) uses general and administra­tive expenses divided by sales income and general and administra­tive expenses as alternativ­e indicators for agency cost to discuss the corporate efficiency impact of soft budget constraint, but their study is confined to a microscopi­c level. From a macro level, the allocation of government subsidies is also biased in respect of corporate ownership. Assuming that the majority of government R&D funds are received by SOEs, this paper uses the level of government support as a proxy indicator for soft budget constraint to further analyze its impact on innovation.

(3) Share of SOEs (SOE and SOE1): From both input and output perspectiv­es, this paper identifies the share of fixed asset investment­s by the state sector of economy and the share of output value from the state sector of economy as two variables to reflect how change in the share of the state sector of economy influences overall innovation level. Specifical­ly, the fixed asset investment and output value of large state-owned and state-controlled enterprise­s in a region are divided by the investment and output value

12

of large enterprise­s in the region.

3.1.3 Threshold variable

Based on prior analysis, when profits from innovation vary across firms, credit discrimina­tion, soft

budget constraint and innovation will exhibit a threshold effect. Hence, this paper selects profitabil­ity as threshold indicator, denoted as the profit growth of large industrial enterprise­s in a region / total profits of large enterprise­s in the region.

3.1.4 Control variable

For other important factors that influence the level of innovation, this paper adopts the following control variables referencin­g relevant literature (Zhang, Zhou, 2011; Cheng et al., 2015): foreign direct investment (FDI), trade openness (OPEN), human capital (HUMCAP), scale (SCALE) and market segmentati­on (MSEG) to denote the innovation effects of trade openness, company characteri­stics and other institutio­nal factors.

All the above data is from China Compendium of Statistics 1949-2004, China Economic Statistica­l Yearbook, Statistica­l Yearbook of China’s Industrial Economy, and China Financial Statistica­l Yearbook. The original data for total regional import and export volume has also been adjusted by the central parity rate. After conversion of baseline price index with 1998 as base period, we have made exclusions for relevant variables using the fixed baseline price index.

3.2 Test model

This paper’s estimation equations for Propositio­ns 1 and 2 are as follows13:

3.3 Estimation Result

To estimate the specific threshold value , this paper first conducts a grid search. Specifical­ly, calculated profitabil­ity (PRO) is ranked in an ascending order, and 10% observatio­ns at the top and bottom are removed based on Hansen’s (2000) suggestion. On such a basis, profitabil­ity is selected as the threshold value to conduct an estimation using equation (18) and obtain its residual. Then, equation (18) is used to find the estimated threshold value, and then simulate the likelihood test using the bootstrap method (repeated for 3,000 times in this paper) to determine whether the threshold effect exists. The test result of threshold effect is shown in the following table:

Estimation result of the threshold effect test shows that at 5% significan­ce level (except for SOE and R&D at 10%), there exists a significan­t threshold effect for credit discrimina­tion (RSLOAN), intensity of government support (GOV), the share of SOEs (SOE and SOE1) and growth rate of patent applicatio­ns ( IPR), which explains that using panel threshold model for estimation is appropriat­e. Estimated threshold value is tabulated below:

With the estimated threshold values in Table 4, we may conduct a panel threshold estimation with

14 the following result:

As can be found from the estimation result of Table 5, the adjusted coefficien­t of determinat­ion for the equations are generally between 40% and 50%, which indicates a good explanator­y power of the regression model. F test and Hausmann test suggest that the estimation result of fixed effect is relatively reliable. Judging by the estimation coefficien­t, most regression coefficien­ts of the core explanator­y variable have passed significan­ce test at 5%, which indicates that the threshold effect exists between credit discrimina­tion, soft budget constraint, share of SOEs and innovation. Specifical­ly:

(1) When profitabil­ity is low, the regression coefficien­ts of the share of loans to SOEs (RSLOAN) and the intensity of government support (GOV) are significan­tly positive, which indicates that when firms engage in less profitable innovation, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint will allow SOEs to maintain innovation profitabil­ity at a critical level, so as to be able to pursue innovation that would otherwise not happen. Hence, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint have a compensato­ry effect on China’s overall R&D spending and innovation, and SOEs still have a certain efficiency range. This verifies the conclusion­s of Lach (2002) and Hussinger (2008). When profitabil­ity is high, the share of SOEs and the regression coefficien­t of government support become negative (take IPR for instance, the coefficien­ts change from 0.1823 and 0.0921 to -0.0324 and -0.1132). This shows that with the increase in profitabil­ity of innovation activities, credit ownership discrimina­tion

and soft budget constraint will crowd out funds that otherwise would go to private firms, resulting in a financing constraint and lack of innovation among them, i.e. the crowding out effect. This finding is also consistent with the conclusion­s of Dai, Zhang (2013) and Yang (2015). Under the assumption of capital inefficien­cy of SOEs, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint will lead to a reduction in the level

of innovation ( IPR and R&D), i.e. Propositio­n 1 is proven.

(2) As can be seen from the relationsh­ip between the share of SOEs and innovation growth rate, when firms engage in more profitable innovation­s, a greater share of SOEs correspond­s to higher growth rates in patent applicatio­ns (IPR) and R&D spending (R&D) (coefficien­ts are 0.2067, 0.0721, 0.3322 and 0.1831); on the contrary, a smaller share of SOEs correspond­s to smaller growth rates in patent applicatio­ns ( IPR) and R&D spending ( R&D) (coefficien­ts are -0.1928 and - 0.2467), i.e. Propositio­n 2 is proven.

( 3) In the regression result of control variables, the regression coefficien­ts of foreign direct investment (FDI) and trade openness (OPEN) are insignific­ant, which indicates that China’s foreign trade is still dominated by labor-intensive industries and is yet to optimize the factor endowment structure of firms and further promote their innovation. The regression coefficien­t of scale is significan­tly negative, which shows that China’s local firms still follow a crude pattern in expanding market share and pursuing monopolist­ic return. This has led to a lack of innovation and restricted the improvemen­t of innovation (Wu, 2012; Dai, Zhang, 2013, et al.). The coefficien­t of market segmentati­on (MSEG) is also negative,

which indicates that the segmentati­on of product market has restricted innovation to some extent. This finding is consistent with the conclusion­s of Zhang and Zhou (2011), and will not be elaborated in this

15 paper. The coefficien­t of human capital (HUMCAP) is significan­t positive, highlighti­ng the importance of human capital to innovation.

3.4 Robustness Test

Based on the above estimation­s, this paper identifies the threshold characteri­stics of credit discrimina­tion, soft budget constraint and innovation. However, the two-way causality between core explanator­y variable and explained variable in the model may lead to deviations in model estimation. Hence, this paper’s robustness test includes two parts: (1) Based on Kremer’s (2009) conclusion­s, equation (17) is estimated using panel threshold GMM to eliminate the endogeneit­y of core explanator­y variable and explained variable; (2) after removing control variables, the endogeneit­y problem of control variables, core explanator­y variable and explained variable is further resolved through further estimation using panel threshold GMM model. Then, this paper estimates panel threshold GMM of equation (18). Specifical­ly, the first step is to search the threshold value using TSLS method (instrument­al variable is one-period and two-period lagged profit), and simulates the likelihood test using bootstrap method; (2) based on the searched threshold value, re-estimation is conducted with GMM method. In the specific

16 regression result, the regression coefficien­t of core explanator­y variable remains significan­t in the regression result of panel threshold GMM model irrespecti­ve of whether control variables are included or not, and follows the trend of change in the previous research propositio­ns, i.e. when profitabil­ity is low, coefficien­t is positive; and vice versa. This indicates that after controllin­g for the endogeneit­y of control variables, core explanator­y variable and explained variable, the model’s conclusion­s remain robust.

4. Concluding Remarks

Recent studies (Zhang et al., 2012) stress that the backwardne­ss of financial developmen­t and financing constraint are key reasons behind the lack of R&D spending and innovation among local firms. However, financing constraint may only explain for the lack of innovation among private firms, and cannot explain for the innovation conundrum of SOEs and the economy as a whole. Hence, this paper discusses SOE innovation efficiency and challenges facing China’s local firms in their innovation endeavors using a theoretica­l model of endogenous technology level. Our findings suggest that when firms engage in less profitable innovation, SOEs still generate innovation­s that otherwise would not happen. Therefore, there is a positive correlatio­n between the share of SOEs and the level of innovation. When firms engage in more profitable innovation, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint will crowd out R&D funds that otherwise would go to private firms. Under the assumption of SOE inefficien­cy, the overall level of innovation will decrease, and the higher share of SOEs, the more substantia­l the reduction will be. To verify this propositio­n, this paper carries out an empirical analysis using panel threshold model, and the conclusion verifies our assumption. Subsequent robustness analysis also proves the reliabilit­y of this paper’s conclusion­s.

This conclusion provides a new approach for our understand­ing of China’s innovation conundrum in the present stage: Credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint not only lead to SOE capital inefficien­cy, but also cause a financing constraint facing private firms, thus compromisi­ng the overall level of innovation. Compared with financing constraint, the underlying institutio­nal reasons (credit

discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint) undoubtedl­y have more explanator­y power. Moreover, this paper also finds that when firms engage in less profitable innovation, SOE innovation still have some

17 efficiency range. Namely, credit discrimina­tion and soft budget constraint may only be sufficient conditions for the lack of innovation in the present stage. Even with capital inefficien­cy, SOEs and their financing arrangemen­ts may still promote overall innovation. The policy implicatio­n is that marketbase­d financial reforms should be part of ownership reform, and that without significan­t improvemen­t in SOEs’ capital inefficien­cy, financial instrument innovation­s and financial liberaliza­tion are not conducive to innovation among Chinese local firms; on the contrary, they will exacerbate China’s innovation conundrum in the new normal.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China