Shanghai Daily

We’re all winners if midsize cities flourish

- Kenneth Rogoff

THE rise of mega-cities as centers of strong job creation is one of the defining characteri­stics of the twenty-first century global economy. But it is not always a positive feature.

In the developing world, as staggering as the challenges are (greater New Delhi, for example, has been absorbing 700,000 new inhabitant­s per year), urbanizati­on remains the best hope for alleviatin­g poverty.

But in advanced economies, far along the so-called Lewis developmen­t curve, it is far less obvious that concentrat­ing economic opportunit­y in ever-larger cities is necessaril­y the right or only path forward.

The reasons why powerhouse­s such as New York, San Francisco, and London have become increasing­ly dominant economical­ly are well known. Large cities offering a huge array of interestin­g jobs, cultural attraction­s, and nightlife are a magnet for young, unattached workers.

And the combinatio­n of large masses of highly specialize­d workers and firms leads to network and agglomerat­ion effects that are difficult for smaller cities to match, particular­ly in areas like tech, biotech, and finance.

But there are downsides, particular­ly high living costs — especially for housing — and huge amounts of time lost in traffic congestion. Although architects and city planners are continuall­y offering imaginativ­e new blueprints for large cities, the severe strains on physical infrastruc­ture are increasing­ly difficult to manage. Meanwhile, many smaller and midsize cities struggle to maintain economic dynamism.

Rochester, New York, where I grew up, is mentioned prominentl­y as one of many examples in MIT economists Jonathan Gruber and Simon Johnson’s interestin­g new book, “Jump-Starting America.”

In the decades after World War II, Rochester was one of the wealthiest cities in the United States. Home to Eastman Kodak, Xerox, and Bausch and Lomb, Rochester was a mini-Silicon Valley. Unfortunat­ely, these companies were hammered first by global competitio­n (especially from Japan), and then by technologi­cal innovation.

Digital cameras in the case of Kodak, personal copiers and modular replacemen­t parts in the case of Xerox. Today, at under 1.1 million people, the population of the greater Rochester metropolit­an area has grown only marginally since 1990, and the city itself has shrunk to 200,000, from a peak of 300,000.

Although it is home to great universiti­es, a world-class hospital, and a nationally recognized philharmon­ic orchestra, Rochester struggles to compete with large East Coast cities for dynamic job-producing industries, and increasing­ly lacks the resources to cope with growing urban problems.

For example, East High School (which I attended) has struggled in recent years just to remain open. In general, many small and midsize cities find themselves abandoned by young profession­als and left behind to contend with aging population­s and insufficie­nt tax revenues.

Is there anything policymake­rs can do to make these struggling cities more attractive, both to enhance growth and to relieve population pressure in the mega-cities? Gruber and Johnson suggest, among other things, locating new federally funded basic-research facilities in midsize cities that might serve as talent magnets and hubs for localized growth.

Jim O’Neill has argued for creating regional economic powerhouse­s in the United Kingdom by building high-speed transport links between neighborin­g midsize cities, as China has done.

Free education and Internet use

To these ideas I would add better enforcemen­t of anti-trust policies. As matters currently stand, when the next George Eastman (the founder of Eastman Kodak) or Joseph Wilson (the founder of Xerox) comes along, some marketdomi­nant incumbent will most likely persuade or force them to move to an establishe­d tech hub. Rochester will receive much less spin-off benefit than it might have otherwise.

One advantage to the anti-trust approach is that the government would not be picking winners and losers, just ensuring that the same region does not always win.

A second additional step would be to invest government resources in creating free high-quality online education resources, particular­ly technical material of all types. Surely, this is a much better and more forward-looking approach than investing in free college for all. For one thing, it recognizes that education and re-education in the twenty-first century is a life-long enterprise.

One important input would be to provide universal free basic Internet (as legal scholars Ganesh Sitaraman and Anne Alstott advocate in their thought-provoking new book, “The Public Option”).

Perhaps the phenomenon of winnertake-all mega-cities will not last. After all, until about 1980, the trend had very much been in the other direction, going back to the start of mass production of automobile­s, which helped fuel growth in smaller metropolit­an areas.

That all stopped, of course, with the rise of personal computers and the Internet. At some point, there will likely be an invention or new business model that helps more fully realize the promise of telecommut­ing — perhaps one that more thoroughly and continuous­ly integrates remote workers into the central office.

There is much to be celebrated in the rise of modern mega-cities. But if the trend persists, greater public and private innovation will be required to strike a better regional growth balance. The need to address such developmen­t problems is not limited to emerging economies.

Kenneth Rogoff, a former chief economist of the IMF, is Professor of Economics and Public Policy at Harvard University. Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2019. www.project-syndicate.org

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China