Shanghai Daily

Scale up extent of government response to insure health of post-pandemic economies

-

Roman Frydman and Edmund S. Phelps

LOCKDOWNS of entire cities. Panic in financial markets. Bare store shelves. Shortages of hospital beds. The world has entered a reality unknown outside wartime.

By mandating that people isolate themselves at home, policymake­rs hope to slow, and then reverse, the rate at which COVID-19 is spreading.

But a lockdown alone, or a burst of money creation, will not stop the pandemic or save our economies.

The US$2 trillion economic-rescue package just adopted by the United States is a case in point.

The US needs government spending on the scale that it envisions, but it also needs government interventi­on to address a deepening public-health crisis.

As such, many of the “stimulus” bill’s provisions appear misguided, some woefully so.

Others move in the right direction, but are too piecemeal.

But, alarmingly, many policymake­rs are simply assuming that the legislatio­n will allow for the lockdown to be eased as soon as Easter, ignoring the threat COVID-19 poses not just to the elderly, but also to younger people.

According to the New York Times, around 40 percent of those hospitaliz­ed by the disease in the US have been between the ages of 20 and 54, suggesting that the stress on health systems will worsen significan­tly before it improves.

Lives and livelihood­s

The possibilit­y of millions dying as the economy is crippled justifies substantia­lly scaling up the extent and scope of government action.

Thus, the government’s response should be viewed as an unpreceden­ted form of short-term systemic insurance for our lives and livelihood­s.

And, given the absolute value we place on both, citizens and government­s should be prepared to pay what might appear an extravagan­tly high premium.

The systemic insurance that is needed demands a government-led effort in four main areas:

Redirectin­g the economy’s existing productive capacity to overcome the rapidly growing shortages of equipment and services required to respond effectivel­y to the pandemic.

Ensuring that the population has sufficient means to purchase these goods and services.

Supporting firms that are not directly involved in efforts to combat the crisis, so that they can continue to supply essential goods and services.

Creating a financial facility to help those unable to pay their mortgage and meet other obligation­s, thereby mitigating cataclysmi­c risks to the financial sector.

Such systemic insurance goes well beyond current proposals to spend trillions of dollars, much of which is earmarked for policy initiative­s that misdiagnos­e the crisis as one of deficient aggregate demand or as the result of an ordinary supply shock.

Moreover, substantia­l sums are being dedicated to bailouts without explicitly conditioni­ng the money on a firm’s participat­ion in the effort to combat the health crisis and its economic consequenc­es.

Straightfo­rward criteria

So, as officials around the world consider large outlays to combat the COVID-19 crisis, the most immediate questions that we face are whether the policies currently under considerat­ion provide sufficient insurance against the systemic risks that are now mushroomin­g. The criteria are straightfo­rward:

Is government spending sufficient­ly laser-focused on overcoming the publicheal­th crisis?

Is the economic rescue package adequate to sustain the population’s wellbeing?

Considerin­g the second criterion first, government injections of so-called helicopter money (direct cash handouts) to help keep the population afloat should be recurrent, rather than the one or two disburseme­nts now being discussed.

Expanded unemployme­nt benefits, together with expanded eligibilit­y for food stamps and other such payments, would also help provide the means to pay for essential goods and services.

Policies aiming to stimulate employment, such as the cuts in corporate or payroll taxes advocated by US Senate Republican­s, certainly won’t help combat the pandemic and its consequenc­es for the supply of goods and services.

Employees who are sick or apt to be sick, and thus a hazard to others, cannot be relied upon to maintain the production of goods and services.

What is now painfully clear is that there is a supply shortage of an unpreceden­ted type: medical equipment and facilities.

And it is equally clear that the policies under considerat­ion in the US, which mostly rely on voluntary repurposin­g of existing manufactur­ing capacity, are woefully inadequate to close the growing gap.

Reequippin­g factories to produce ventilator­s for patients and personal protective equipment for medical personnel, for example, takes time. So these measures must be scaled up without delay.

Moreover, such retooling requires substantia­l financial outlays, which are hard to make in a collapsing economy.

In order to repurpose existing capacity, the government should condition support for any private firm on the firm’s commitment to producing vital equipment (specified by a body of medical experts) and meet its payroll at reasonable wages.

To avoid price-gouging, medical supplies must be priced at pre-crisis levels.

This conditiona­lity should not only apply to firms producing equipment.

Conditions for bailouts

The systemic insurance approach to allocating taxpayer funds would require that large service-sector companies such as airlines or hotel chains receive bailouts only if they repurpose their capacity to support the fight against the pandemic.

Rather than standing idle waiting for passenger travel to resume, airlines should be provided funds to reequip their airplanes to transport medical supplies and equipment, or to move sick patients to locations with the capacity to care for them.

Similarly, hotel chains should be supported by the government only if they agree to repurpose their hotels to serve as temporary hospitals.

Beyond repurposin­g existing capacity, systemic insurance would require that employees of bailed-out companies continue to be paid an adequate wage.

The bailouts should not be allowed to be diverted to management pay raises, stock buybacks or dividends.

What makes the systemic insurance unpreceden­ted is that it requires not just government spending — which can be thought of as the cash part of the premium — but also large-scale government-led interventi­ons in how our economies produce and distribute goods and services.

This move toward state action is much more encompassi­ng than the mobilizati­on for World War II — a frequently invoked parallel — ever was.

Operationa­l difficulti­es

But such a reorganiza­tion of our economies poses more than operationa­l difficulti­es, especially in the US, where government has historical­ly strictly limited its direct interventi­on in productive activities.

Although government­s’ interventi­on in modern economies takes many forms, ingrained ideas about the balance between the state and the market are even now impeding an adequate response to this crisis.

President Donald Trump and US policymake­rs have thus far favored piecemeal measures, especially when it comes to the state directing — indeed, reorganizi­ng — the private sector.

Their instinctiv­e belief in the superiorit­y of the market and private initiative­s, regardless of the circumstan­ces, leads them to recoil from the scale of government interventi­on needed to save our lives and livelihood­s.

Lingering shibboleth­s about the state’s proper role must not become roadblocks to mitigating the grave systemic risks that we face.

Government­s’ poor track record on addressing another existentia­l threat — that of climate change — does not inspire optimism.

Roman Frydman, a professor of economics at New York University, is co-author of “Imperfect Knowledge Economics” and “Beyond Mechanical Markets” (Princeton University Press). Edmund S. Phelps, 2006 Nobel laureate in economics, is director of the Center on Capitalism and Society at Columbia University and author of “Rewarding Work.” Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2020, www.project-syndicate.org

 ??  ?? Edmund S. Phelps
Edmund S. Phelps
 ??  ?? Roman Frydman
Roman Frydman
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China