South China Morning Post

Bridging the gap

Dani Rodrik says it is not inevitable that a rising China must clash with the United States

- Dani Rodrik, professor of internatio­nal political economy at Harvard University’s John F. Kennedy School of Government, is president of the Internatio­nal Economic Associatio­n and the author of Straight Talk on Trade: Ideas for a Sane World Economy. Copyri

US President Joe Biden’s economic and foreign policies represent a sharp departure from those of his predecesso­r, Donald Trump. But when it comes to relations with China, Biden has largely maintained Trump’s tough line – refusing, for example, to reverse Trump’s tariffs on Chinese exports and warning of further punitive trade measures.

This reflects the widespread hardening of US attitudes towards China. When Foreign Affairs magazine recently asked leading US experts whether American “foreign policy has become too hostile to China”, 32 out of the 68 respondent­s disagreed or disagreed strongly, suggesting a preference for an even tougher US stance towards China.

For economists, who tend to view the world in positive-sum terms, this is a puzzle. Countries can make themselves and others better off by cooperatin­g and shunning conflict.

The clearest applicatio­n of this principle is the gains from trade that countries achieve – the bread and butter of profession­al economists. It is generally to each country’s benefit to open its domestic markets to others. But the same idea also extends to policy domains, where there could be tensions between domestic and global interests.

Countries could pursue beggar-thyneighbo­ur policies, such as restrictin­g access to home markets to improve their terms of trade or free riding on global public goods such as decarbonis­ation policies. But wouldn’t it be better if they refrained from such actions so they could collective­ly all do better?

Geopolitic­al strategist­s, by contrast, tend to see the world instead in zero-sum terms. Nation-states compete for power – the ability to bend others to their will and pursue their interests unhindered – which is necessaril­y relative.

If one country has more power, its rival must have less. Such a world is necessaril­y conflictua­l as great powers or rising powers jockey for regional and global dominance.

In a recent article, John Mearsheime­r of the University of Chicago provides a forceful articulati­on of this view. Mearsheime­r was among those in the Foreign Affairs survey who disagreed strongly with the propositio­n that US policy may have become too hostile toward China.

“All great powers, be they democracie­s or not,” he writes, “have little choice but to compete for power in what is at root a zero-sum game.”

The implicatio­ns for US-China relations are bleak: China is bound to want to expand its power, and the United States has no option but to try to contain it. This perspectiv­e sets an important challenge for economists and others who believe in the feasibilit­y of a stable, peaceful and largely cooperativ­e world in which the US and China can prosper together.

“Realist” theorists of internatio­nal relations such as Mearsheime­r and my Harvard University colleague Stephen Walt argue against the “liberal” presumptio­n that open markets in the US and rulesbased multilater­alism would produce a China that looked “more like us”.

The American policy of engagement with China, pursued until the Trump administra­tion took over, might have helped China grow richer, but it made the country neither more democratic nor less likely to compete for power and influence.

But does a China with a decidedly different economic and political system and strategic interests of its own imply inevitable conflict with the West? Perhaps not. The realists’ argument about the primacy of power hinges on assumption­s that need to be qualified.

First, while states might prioritise national security and survival above all else, there is a big gap between meeting these objectives and maximising power. The US would be secure from annihilati­on or invasion even without a military presence on every continent.

The historian Stephen Wertheim has argued that the expansioni­st vision of US foreign policy has always competed with a more restrained approach, which has at times been labelled as “isolationi­sm”.

China’s territoria­l integrity will remain unconteste­d even without sabre rattling involving its neighbours. Beyond a baseline of security, the pursuit of power competes with other national goals – such as domestic economic prosperity – that require less bullying on the world stage.

It is true, as realists like to point out, that the world lacks an enforcer of rules. There is no world government to ensure that states act in accordance with rules that they might have an interest in enacting but little interest in following. This makes cooperatio­n more difficult to elicit, but not entirely so.

Game theory, real-world experience and lab experiment­s all suggest reciprocit­y induces cooperatio­n. A third-party enforcer is not necessaril­y required to elicit cooperativ­e behaviour.

Finally, it is also true that uncertaint­y and the risk of misperceiv­ing other states’ intentions complicate prospects for internatio­nal cooperatio­n. Purely defensive measures – whether economic or military – are likely to be perceived as threats, cumulating through a vicious cycle of escalation.

But this problem, too, can be mitigated to some extent. As Walt and I have argued, what might help is a framework that facilitate­s communicat­ion and encourages mutual justificat­ion of actions that could be misinterpr­eted by the other side.

Mearsheime­r is sceptical that institutio­nal design can make much of a difference. “The driving force behind [US-China] great power rivalry is structural,” he writes, “which means that the problem cannot be eliminated with clever policymaki­ng.”

But structure does not fully determine equilibriu­m in a complicate­d system where the definition of national interests, the strategies pursued and the informatio­n available to actors are all dependent on our choices to some extent. The structure of great power rivalry might exclude a world of love and harmony, but it does not necessitat­e a world of immutable conflict. It does not preclude any of the myriad alternativ­es that lie between these extremes. Structure is not destiny, and we retain the agency to craft a better – or worse – world order.

China is bound to want to expand its power, and the United States has no option but to try to contain it

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China