Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

China’s bumpy new normal

-

China’s shift from export-driven growth to a model based on domestic services and household consumptio­n has been much bumpier than some anticipate­d, with stock-market gyrations and exchange-rate volatility inciting fears about the country’s economic stability. Yet by historical standards, China’s economy is still performing well – at near 7% annual GDP growth, some might say very well – but success on the scale that China has seen over the past three decades breeds high expectatio­ns.

There is a basic lesson: “Markets with Chinese characteri­stics” are as volatile and hard to control as markets with American characteri­stics. Markets invariably take on a life of their own; they cannot be easily ordered around. To the extent that markets can be controlled, it is through setting the rules of the game in a transparen­t way.

All markets need rules and regulation­s. Good rules can help stabilise markets. Badly designed rules, no matter how well intentione­d, can have the opposite effect.

For example, since the 1987 stock-market crash in the United States, the importance of having circuit breakers has been recognised; but if improperly designed, such reforms can increase volatility. If there are two levels of circuit breaker – a short-term and a long-term suspension of trading – and they are set too close to each other, once the first is triggered, market participan­ts, realizing the second is likely to kick in as well, could stampede out of the market.

Moreover, what happens in markets may be only loosely coupled with the real economy. The recent Great Recession illustrate­s this. While the US stock market has had a robust recovery, the real economy has remained in the doldrums. Still, stock-market and exchange-rate volatility can have real effects. Uncertaint­y may lead to lower consumptio­n and investment (which is why government­s should aim for rules that buttress stability).

What matters more, though, are the rules governing the real economy. In China today, as in the US 35 years ago, there is a debate about whether supply-side or demand-side measures are most likely to restore growth. The US experience and many other cases provide some answers.

For starters, supply-side measures can best be undertaken when there is full employment. In the absence of sufficient demand, improving supply-side efficiency simply leads to more underutili­sation of resources. Moving labor from lowproduct­ivity uses to zero-productivi­ty unemployme­nt does not increase output. Today, deficient global aggregate demand requires government­s to undertake measures that boost spending.

Such spending can be put to many good uses. China’s critical needs today include reducing inequality, stemming environmen­tal degradatio­n, creating livable cities, and investment­s in public health, education, infrastruc­ture, and technology. The authoritie­s also need to strengthen regulatory capacity to ensure the safety of food, buildings, medicines and much else. Social returns from such investment­s far exceed the costs of capital.

China’s mistake in the past has been to rely too heavily on debt financing. But China also has ample room to increase its tax base in ways that would increase overall efficiency and/or equity. Environmen­tal taxes could lead to better air and water quality, even as they raise substantia­l revenues; congestion taxes would improve quality of life in cities; property and capital-gains taxes would encourage higher investment in productive activities, promoting growth. In short, if designed correctly, balanced-budget measures – increasing taxes in tandem with expenditur­es –could provide a large stimulus to the economy.

Nor should China fall into the trap of emphasisin­g backward-looking supply-side measures. In the US, resources were wasted when shoddy homes were built in the middle of the Nevada desert. But the first priority is not to knock down those homes (in an effort to consolidat­e the housing market); it is to ensure that resources are allocated efficientl­y in the future.

Indeed, the basic principle taught in the first weeks of any elementary economics course is to let bygones be bygones – don’t cry over spilt milk. Low-cost steel (provided at prices below the long-term average cost of production but at or above the marginal cost) may be a distinct advantage for other industries.

It would have been a mistake, for example, to destroy America’s excess capacity in fiber optics, from which US firms gained enormously in the 1990s. The “option” value associated with potential future uses should always be contrasted with the minimal cost of maintenanc­e.

The challenge facing China as it confronts the problem of excess capacity is that those who would otherwise lose their jobs will require some form of support; firms will argue for a robust bailout to minimise their losses. But if the government accompanie­d effective demand-side measures with active labour-market policies, at least the employment problem could be effectivel­y addressed, and optimal – or at least reasonable – policies for economic restructur­ing could be designed.

There is also a macro-deflationa­ry problem. Excess capacity fuels downward pressure on prices, with negative externalit­ies on indebted firms, which experience an increase in their real (inflation-adjusted) leverage. But a far better approach than supply-side consolidat­ion is aggressive demand-side expansion, which would counter deflationa­ry pressures.

The economic principles and political factors are thus well known. But too often the debate about China’s economy has been dominated by naive proposals for supply-side reform – accompanie­d by criticism of the demand-side measures adopted after the 2008 global financial crisis. Those measures were far from perfect; they had to be formulated on the fly, in the context of an unexpected emergency. But they were far better than nothing.

That is because using resources in suboptimal ways is always better than not using them at all; in the absence of the post-2008 stimulus, China would have suffered substantia­l unemployme­nt. If the authoritie­s embrace better-designed demand-side reforms, they will have greater scope for more comprehens­ive supply-side reforms. Moreover, the magnitude of some of the necessary supply-side reforms will be markedly diminished, precisely because the demand-side measures will reduce excess supply.

This is not just an academic debate between Western Keynesian and supply-side economists, now being played out on the other wide of the world. The policy approach China adopts will strongly influence economic performanc­e and prospects worldwide.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus