Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

The end of free-lunch economics

- By Raghuram Rajan © Project Syndicate, 2022. www.project-syndicate.org

Smart economic policymaki­ng invariably requires trading off some pain today for greater future gains. But this is a difficult propositio­n politicall­y, especially in democracie­s.

It is always easier for elected leaders to indulge their constituen­ts immediatel­y, on the hope that the bill will not arrive while they are still in office. Moreover, those who bear the pain caused by a policy are not necessaril­y those who will gain from it.

That is why today’s more advanced economies created mechanisms that allow them to make hard choices when necessary. Chief among these are independen­t central banks and mandated limits on budget deficits. Importantl­y, political parties reached a consensus to establish and back these mechanisms irrespecti­ve of their own immediate political priorities.

One reason why many emerging markets have swung from crisis to crisis is that they failed to achieve such consensus. But recent history shows that developed economies, too, are becoming less tolerant of pain, perhaps because their own political consensus has eroded.

Financial markets have become volatile once again, owing to fears that the US Federal Reserve will have to tighten its monetary policy significan­tly to control inflation. But many investors still hope that the Fed will go easy if asset prices start to fall substantia­lly. If the Fed proves them right, it will become that much harder to normalize financial conditions in the future.

Investors’ hope that the Fed will prolong the party is not baseless. In late 1996, Fed Chair Alan Greenspan warned of financial markets’ “irrational exuberance.” But the markets shrugged off the warning and were proved correct.

Perhaps chastened by the harsh political reaction to Greenspan’s speech, the Fed did nothing. And when the stock market eventually crashed in 2000, the Fed cut rates, ensuring that the recession was mild.

In a testimony to the congressio­nal Joint Economic Committee the previous year, Greenspan argued that while the Fed could not prevent “the inevitable economic hangover” from an asset-price boom, it could “mitigate the fallout when it occurs and, hopefully, ease the transition to the next expansion.”

The Fed thus assured traders and bankers that if they collective­ly gambled on similar assets, it would not limit the upside, but it would limit the downside if their bets turned bad. Subsequent Fed interventi­ons have entrenched such beliefs, making it even harder for the Fed to rein in financial markets with modest moves. And now that much more tightening and consequent pain may be needed, a consensus in favor of it might be harder to achieve.

Fiscal policy is also guilty of peddling supposedly painless economic measures. Most would agree that the pandemic created a need for targeted spending (through extended, generous unemployme­nt benefits, for example) to shield the hardest-hit households. But, in the event, the spending was anything but targeted. The US Congress passed multitrill­ion-dollar bills offering something for everyone.

The Paycheck Protection Program (PPP), for example, provided $800 billion in grants (effectivel­y) for small businesses across the board.

A new study from MIT’s David Autor and his colleagues estimates that the program helped preserve 2-3 million jobyears of employment over 14 months, at a stupendous cost of $170,000-$257,000 per job-year. Worse, only 23-34% of this money went directly to workers who would otherwise have lost their jobs. The balance went to creditors, business owners, and shareholde­rs. All told, an estimated threequart­ers of PPP benefits went to the top one-fifth of earners.

At what cost?

Of course, the program may have saved some firms that otherwise would have collapsed. But at what cost?

While capitalist­s anticipate profits, they also sign up for possible failure. Moreover, many small businesses are tiny operations without much organizati­onal capital.

If a small bakery had to close, the economic fallout would have been mitigated by the enhanced unemployme­nt insurance. And if it had a loyal clientele, it could restart after the pandemic, perhaps with a little help from a bank.

The standard line is that the unconstrai­ned spending was driven by a sense that unpreceden­ted times called for unpreceden­ted measures. In fact, it was the response to the 2008 global financial crisis that broke the previous consensus for more prudent policies.

Lasting public resentment that Wall Street had been helped more than Main Street motivated politician­s in both major parties to spend with abandon when the pandemic hit. But targeted unemployme­nt benefits were associated with the Democrats, leaving Republican­s seeking wins for their own constituen­cies. Who better to support than small businesses?

While political fractures were driving up untargeted spending, budget hawks were nowhere to be found: Their voices had been steadily drowned out by economists. In addition to the cranks who show up periodical­ly to advocate ostensibly free lunches through money-financed spending, a growing chorus of mainstream economists had been arguing that prevailing low interest rates gave developed countries significan­tly more room to expand fiscal deficits.

Politician­s who were eager to justify their policies ignored these economists’ caveats – that spending had to be sensible, and that interest rates had to stay low. Only the headline message mattered, and anyone suggesting otherwise was dismissed as a hair-shirt fanatic.

Historical­ly, it has been the Fed’s job to take away the monetary punch bowl before the party gets frenzied, and Congress’s job to be prudent about fiscal deficits and debt. But the Fed’s desire to spare the market from pain has driven more risk-taking, and reinforced expectatio­ns of further interventi­ons. The Fed’s actions have also added to the pressure on Congress to do its bit for Main Street, which in turn has led to inflation and a belief that the Fed will back off from raising rates.

All of this makes a return to the previous consensus more difficult. When the Fed does raise rates significan­tly, the government’s costs of servicing the debt from past spending will limit future spending, including on policies to reduce inequality (which has fueled political fragmentat­ion), combat future emergencie­s, and tackle climate change.

Every economy has a limited reservoir of policy credibilit­y and resources, which are best used to mitigate genuine economic distress, not to shield those who can bear some pain. If everyone wants a free lunch, the bill eventually will be paid by those least able to afford it. Emerging-market economies have had to learn this the hard way. Developed countries may have to learn it again.

Raghuram G. Rajan, former governor of the Reserve Bank of India, is Professor of Finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and the author, most recently, of The Third Pillar: How Markets and the State Leave the Community Behind (Penguin, 2020).

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus