Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

The IMF’s unfinished business

- By Joseph E. Stiglitz and Kevin Gallagher

The Internatio­nal Monetary Fund is showing promising signs of changing with the times. In addition to recognizin­g that climate change poses significan­t risks to financial stability, it has responded to the pandemic with a major new allocation of special drawing rights (the Fund’s reserve asset), while criticizin­g the G20’s inadequate framework for dealing with debt distress.

Moreover, in a recent agreement with Argentina, the Fund has largely abandoned the kind of austerity programs that have long plagued its reputation, not to mention undercutti­ng livelihood­s around the world.

The IMF will have a chance to take another major step in the right direction when it reviews its stance on capital-flow regulation later this month. The original rationale for such regulation, enshrined in the IMF’s Articles of Agreement, was that cross-border capital flows could disrupt internatio­nal financial markets, the stability of which was the IMF’s raison d’être.

Yet, ironically, in the Fund’s darker days during the 1980s and 1990s, it made bailout packages conditiona­l on recipients deregulati­ng financial flows; and in the late 1990s, it even tried to change the Articles of Agreement to outlaw capital-flow regulation.

But the 1997-98 East Asian financial crisis, which resulted largely from capital-market deregulati­on, sidelined that effort. After those tumultuous years, many middle-income countries pushed back against the IMF’s drive for capitalmar­ket liberaliza­tion and “self-insured” against capital-flow volatility by accumulati­ng foreign-exchange reserves and implementi­ng capital-account measures.

For many countries, capital flows are important for sustaining investment and growth. But some of the IMF’s own research shows that internatio­nal capital flows to emerging market and developing countries (EMDCs) tend to be highly unstable, surging when interest rates are low in the United States, only to undergo “sudden stops” when monetary conditions tighten. While the surges push up exchange rates and encourage EMDC companies and households to borrow excessivel­y, the sudden stops derail growth, weaken exchange rates, and drive up debt to unsustaina­ble levels. The resulting crises take an enormous toll on these countries’ economies and citizens.

Recent advances in economic theory have proved that capital controls can make markets more efficient, not less.

In 2011, Anton Korinek published an article in the IMF Economic Review showing that capital flows generate negative externalit­ies because individual investors and borrowers are focused only on their portfolios, not on how their decisions may affect financial stability.

Just as the absence of pollution controls results in excessive pollution, the absence of capital-account controls can lead to excessive capital inflows.

The following year, the IMF issued a new “institutio­nal view” acknowledg­ing that capital-flow deregulati­on is not optimal for most EMDCs, and that capital controls can indeed be effective under certain circumstan­ces. And, to reduce the stigma, it rebranded such regulation­s as “capital flow management measures” (CFMs).

Yet the effects of this shift remained limited, owing to resistance from major IMF shareholde­rs, financial lobbies, and intransige­nt economists inside and outside the institutio­n, who argued for unfettered financial markets and massive bailouts when things went awry.

In the end, it became IMF policy to recommend CFMs only as a last resort, after a government had exhausted all other possibilit­ies, even though this was a decidedly ideologica­l position with no basis in prevailing economic theory. Academic economists and the IMF’s own researcher­s have shown that capital controls are most effective when they are deployed alongside other policies, not used in isolation.

Less impact

Moreover, forthcomin­g research from one of us (Gallagher), Luma Ramos, and Lara Merling, suggests that the IMF’s new institutio­nal view actually had less of an impact on its behavior than proponents might have hoped – even after its new position had been tightly circumscri­bed.

The Fund simply did not pay much more attention to capital-flow volatility in the decade after the policy was adopted; and when it issued advice on capital-account regulation­s, its prescripti­ons were inconsiste­nt across countries.

Even in the early days of the COVID-19 crisis, when EMDCs experience­d massive capital flight, which predictabl­y depreciate­d exchange rates and pushed many countries into debt distress, the IMF remained reluctant to advise countries to regulate capital flows.

But things began to change this past December when the IMF admitted that it should have sanctioned CFMs in its failed Argentina program, which has now been renegotiat­ed and will take effect pending approval by the Fund’s board.

Another problem, however, is that even as the IMF has slowly changed its own stance on capital controls, trade and investment treaties have further curtailed countries’ ability to regulate capital flows.

A recent study analyzing more than 200 trade and investment agreements finds that the majority of those between advanced economies and EMDCs not only prohibit capital controls but also allow private financial firms to challenge government­s directly through dispute-settlement bodies that tend to favor the firms. Worse, treaties outlawing capital-flow regulation are fast becoming the norm, and cases against government­s are on the rise.

At this month’s review, the IMF’s board should press for four reforms to the Fund’s capital-account policy.

First, the IMF must clearly advise member countries to enact permanent regulation­s allowing for the rapid deployment of CFMs during surges and sudden stops.

Second, it must recommend that CFMs be part of a multiprong­ed approach, rather than used only as a last resort.

Third, the IMF should advocate reforms to trade and investment treaties to grant EMDCs more policy leeway for using CFMs.

And, fourth, the IMF must set aside time to train its staff to implement these policies in a consistent and evenhanded manner.

Given the possibilit­y that interest-rate hikes and Russia’s war in Ukraine will trigger massive capital flight and a global debt crisis, it is critical that the IMF embrace capital controls and the role they can play in helping member states mitigate financial instabilit­y. The world economy may well depend on it.

Joseph E. Stiglitz, a Nobel laureate in economics, is University Professor at Columbia University and a member of the Independen­t Commission for the Reform of Internatio­nal Corporate Taxation. Kevin P. Gallagher is a professor and Director of the Global Developmen­t Policy Center at Boston University.

© Project Syndicate, 2022.*

 ?? ??
 ?? ??
 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus