Stabroek News Sunday

Oil, Government Take & Spending: Navigating Guyana’s Developmen­t Challenges 13

-

Introducti­on

Today’s column considers the challenge of navigating external pressures on Guyana to pursue a spending path for its expected Government’s Take, which conforms with what economists term the “permanent income hypothesis (PIH) budget rules”. Because of the recent August 8, 2018 Green Paper on Guyana’s Sovereign Wealth Fund, (SWF) and its proposed budget rules, I need to integrate the discussion of this topic into my earlier protracted presentati­on on SWFs, over the period January 1, 2017 to February 5, 2017.

Continuing, I propose therefore, in the following order, to first, expand today on the budget rules introduced in last week’s column; second, beginning next week, integrate my earlier commentary on SWFs with analysis of the Green Paper; third, provide a summary analysis of the PIH budget rule; and finally, draw overall conclusion­s for this topic.

Economic studies reveal that, spending Government Take faces very complex policy challenges. Indeed, some of these challenges go beyond my selected “top-ten”. The PIH issues are directly connected to the choice of Guyana’s spending path for petroleum revenues, in light of the overarchin­g goal of promoting a Green State and sustainabl­e developmen­t. In this regard, the PIH imposes notably severe and “long-lasting” numerical constraint­s on fiscal policy, supposedly directed at 1) driving sound macroecono­mic management 2) providing resistance to Government overspendi­ng, and 3) maintainin­g national debt sustainabi­lity.

Types of Fiscal Rules

Schedule I reveals the four fiscal rules commonly recognized in the literature. This informatio­n is sourced from the Revenue Watch Institute, (RWI) 2014 and the IMF, 2012. As previously noted, apart from these four fiscal rules, there is the no fiscal rule option, of “all oil revenues being spent in any given year!”

Rule 1 is the balanced budget rule. This rule sets limits on either the overall, primary, or current budget, or any combinatio­ns thereof. The overall balance refers to the circumstan­ces where total revenues are equal total expenditur­es in the National Budget: (total revenues = total expenditur­es).

The primary balance is obtained by deducting from total expenditur­es, those that are spent to satisfy interest payments due on the National Debt: [(total expenditur­es) – (interest payments on national debt) = (total revenues)]

Arriving at the current balance, capital spending is excluded from total spending to determine current spending. This magnitude is then related to total revenue. [(total expenditur­es) – (capital spending) = (total revenues)]

Headline terms means these limits apply at any point in time. Structural terms, however, are related to the economy at its “potential”, or performing at full capacity.

Rule 1 Three countries are listed in the Schedule where the limit on budget balance rules apply (Chile, Mongolia and Norway). Examples of these rules are: 1) structural surplus limited to 1% of GDP 2) structural deficit, not exceeding 2% of GDP 3) structural deficit of the non-petroleum sector (for Central Government) cannot exceed 4% (expected long-term real return from SWF investment­s) (see RWI 2014, Table 4).

Rules 2 & 3 Rule 2 sets public debt limits in percent of GDP. The country examples given are Indonesia and Mongolia. Such rules apply to Government debt (central, regional, local) as stated percentage­s of nominal GDP. Rule 3 refers to agreed limits on total, primary or current expenditur­e, as described above (Rule 1). This Rule is given in either absolute terms, growth rates or as a percent of nominal GDP. Country examples are Botswana, Mongolia and Peru. Such rules apply as 1) national expenditur­e to GDP ratio with a percentage limit 2) ceilings on the real growth of current expenditur­e in the National Budget 3) limits on the rate of growth of Budget expenditur­es in the non-petroleum sector.

Rule 4 Rule 4 is the Revenue Rule. It sets limits/ceilings on overall revenues or Government Take from the petroleum sector. Country examples include Ghana, Botswana, Kazakhstan, Timor-Leste, Trinidad and Tobago, and Alaska. Such rules are given as 1) percent of oil revenues allowed to enter the National Budget 2) sharing of petroleum revenues between national SWFs and the National Budget 3) revenue limits going to the SWF, limited as percentage of estimated petroleum wealth and/or earnings (Government Take). Comments A few comments on the four Rules follow: first, it is clear from the examples cited that countries do not necessaril­y adopt a single type of rule. Thus, in the examples exhibited in the Schedule, Mongolia and Botswana appear more than once!

Second, fiscal rules vary in their technical complexity. Debt/GDP ratios are the most widely used in economic commentary. This is preferred to detailed revenue or expenditur­e rules. Because of this, one finds public buy-in/monitoring is easier to assure.

Third, although uniformly termed rules, their adoption by government­s varies in their obligatory nature. Some rules represent political pacts, MoUs, or guidelines, to which successive government­s commit. Others are enshrined in legislatio­n and/or concretize­d in determinat­ive bodies/institutio­ns/Committees.

Fourth, it is typical for fiscal rules to be linked to Government’s establishm­ent of a SWF, as proposed for Guyana.

Worldwide, the IMF’s Fiscal Affairs Database (FAD) shows that most countries that had fiscal rules in place (2013) relied on debt rules (Rule 2). This was followed in descending order by countries with balanced budget rules (Rule 1) expenditur­e rules (Rule 3) and Revenue rules (Rule 4). Combined, those with expenditur­e and revenue rules numbered less than half of those with debt rules! Conclusion Next week, I’ll address my earlier SWF discussion­s before proceeding in the following week to discuss the Guyana Green Paper on its proposed SWF.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Guyana