Business Standard

Britain’s ‘austerity’ election

How the United Kingdom shows that fiscal consolidat­ion is economical­ly and politicall­y beneficial

- DEEPAK LAL

Iwas in London in early April and watched the televised debate of the political leaders contesting the national election. I watched in amazement as, apart from the Conservati­ve and the UK Independen­ce Party leaders, all the others laid into what were labelled the “austerity” policies followed by the Conservati­ve-Liberal Democrat coalition to deal with the massive Budget deficit left by the preceding Labour government. The most strident was the leader of the Scottish National Party (SNP), Nicola Sturgeon, who was completely against any austerity — whilst the others, including Labour’s Ed Miliband and Lib Dems’ Nick Clegg seemed to be echoing variants of St Augustine’s plea in his Confession­s: “Give me chastity and continency — but not yet!”

After this debate, despite the dead heat predicted by all the pollsters, I did not believe that when it came to the ballot box the majority of English voters would be able to cast their vote without choking in favour of Labour’s Mr Miliband and his Shadow Chancellor Ed Balls — the architects of Labour’s incontinen­ce under Gordon Brown. When the prospect of a Labour government kept in office in a hung Parliament by the SNP, which promised a more extreme version of the last Labour government’s fiscal excesses, even the waverers must have baulked. So I was not surprised when the BBC’s exit poll predicted a Conservati­ve victory.

But the election outcome also provides another lesson. Though many academics and much of the commentari­at had argued against the speed, and some even on the need for the coalition’s contractio­nary fiscal adjustment on traditiona­l Keynesian grounds, their fears that these policies could lead to another slump were belied by the actual outcomes in terms of unemployme­nt and even growth. This must have given credence to the Tory claim that they needed another five years to complete the task of fiscal consolidat­ion and put Britain on a path of sustainabl­e growth.

There are also lessons to be learnt about the crude Keynesiani­sm propounded by much of the commentari­at and many academics during the Great Recession. They have repeated the opprobrium hurled at the fiscal consolidat­ion undertaken by the first Thatcher government, when 364 UK economists wrote a letter to The Times denouncing it, claiming it would lead to a slump. I refused to sign the letter. Thatcher’s fiscal consolidat­ion was followed by robust growth.

Furthermor­e, a group of Italian economists at Bocconi University have considered a number of other fiscal consolidat­ion and questioned the standard Keynesian claim that they necessaril­y depress demand and output. Instead, they identify what they describe by the malapropis­m “expansiona­ry fiscal contractio­n” (see Alberto Alesina and Silvia Ardagna’s 2009 NBER working paper, titled “Large Changes in Fiscal policy: Taxes versus Spending”).

The British monetarist Tim Congdon (in his article “In praise of expansiona­ry fiscal contractio­n”, which appeared in Economic Affairs this year) has provided some support. He examines the change in the cyclically adjusted public sector net borrowing (PSBR), with a reduction representi­ng fiscal tightening, and sees if it is accompanie­d by below trend growth and a reduction in the “output gap” with more spare capacity and higher unemployme­nt. The “output gap” is measured with reference to the level of potential output when unemployme­nt is at the monetarist “natural rate” — that is, the non-accelerati­ng inflation rate of unemployme­nt (Nairu). The “output gap” is then given by the percentage difference between actual gross domestic product (GDP) in constant prices and estimated potential GDP. So abovepoten­tial output is associated with a positive value of the output gap and beneath-potential output with a negative value. (See OECD Economic Outlook 1995, page 74). Mr Congdon’s estimates of the changes in the output gap and in the PSBR for 1981 to 2013 for the United Kingdom from the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund are in the table. If the Keynesian view is valid, one should see an inverse relationsh­ip between changes in the cyclically adjusted Budget balance (PSBR) and changes in the output gap.

There are five phases from 1980 in the table. During the first, 1981-88, the Thatcher government’s fiscal policy was contractio­nary, but the output gap improved, refuting the claims of the 364 economists who had signed the letter to The Times. From 1989 to 1993, fiscal policy was expansiona­ry, to counter the downturn associated with membership of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism, leading to a worsening of the output gap. From 1994 to 2000, which includes the early years of the Blair government, fiscal policy was contractio­nary with an improvemen­t in the output gap. Thereafter from 2001 to 2009, in Mr Brown’s fiscal expansion there was a worsening of the output gap. Under George Osborne in the Conservati­ve-Lib Dem coalition, fiscal policy was again tightened and contrary to the academic and media Jeremiahs, there was an improvemen­t in the output gap.

Three conclusion­s follow about macroecono­mic policy. First, Keynesian counter-cyclical policies do not work, justifying the convention­al policy prescripti­ons accepted till the Great Recession. Fiscal policies should be concerned with the microecono­my, the financing of public goods, and maintainin­g fiscal and debt sustainabi­lity. Second, business cycle fluctuatio­ns should be managed by monetary policy. Third, the fear of the ineffectiv­eness of monetary policy because of a purported Keynesian “liquidity trap” is unwarrante­d. As Ben Bernanke wearing his academic hat wrote, “The general argument that the monetary authoritie­s can increase aggregate demand and prices, even if the nominal interest rate is zero, is as follows: Money, unlike other forms of government debt, pays zero interest and has infinite maturity. The monetary authoritie­s can issue as much money as they like. Hence if the price level was truly independen­t of money issuance, then the monetary authoritie­s could use the money they create to acquire indefinite quantities of goods and assets. This is manifestly impossible in equilibriu­m … This is an elementary argument, but … it is quite corrosive of claims of monetary impotence” (“Japanese Monetary Policy: A case of self-induced paralysis”, A Posen and R Mikitani (editors), Japan’s Financial Crisis and its Parallels to US Experience, 2009).

Finally, politicall­y, the result of the UK election shows that a government undertakin­g austerity for credible fiscal and debt sustainabi­lity need not fear the electoral consequenc­es.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India