Business Standard

An idea of medieval India

-

de-urbanisati­on and de-industrial­isation and has offered his comments on the basis of available evidence on these issues, which have been debated by other historians dealing with this important phase of Indian history.

The first chapter, “The Agrarian Order under the Delhi Sultanate 1206-1398,” shows that though, at the start of the Sultanate, agricultur­e was quite developed, the area under cultivatio­n was limited and forests were quite extensive. Wells, canals were developed and wheat, pepper, opium, and so on were produced, as was the “largest volume of cotton in the world”. The extensive forest and waste lands that coexisted with fullfledge­d agricultur­e, says the author, “provided the basis for the existence of communitie­s” following different occupation­s on the basis of the division of labour reflecting the caste system. Multiple and diverse economic activities existed under the Alauddin Khilji regime and “after the crops were removed from the fields the produce had to be subjected to different kind of processing which constitute­d a species of rural manufactur­e”.

If, on the one hand, what we have been able to find out about agricultur­e and rural manufactur­es shows that the three centuries cannot be described as “unchanging or moribund in any sense”, on the other, the picture was scarcely rosy for the ordinary peasant and village labourer who lived under “the ever-present threat of pauperizat­ion”.

Rulers, whether Alauddin Khilji (12961316) or Muhammad bin Tughlaq (13241351), depended on financial resources based on “agrarian taxation policies and approaches”. When tax demands were impossibly heavy, “the people left their cattle… and fled into the jungle”. At the same time, peasants also revolted against oppressive taxation, and Firoz Shah (1351) made “the beginning of a regime, under which pressure upon peasants was much eased”. State policies, thus, played a major role in agrarian life, including in interventi­ons during famine.

In chapter 2, “Towns, Manufactur­es, Trade and Finance, 1206-1398”, the larger point that deserves to be made here is that India’s natural processes of economic growth were at work in the medieval age. As the author observes, “From the thirteenth century…not only the arrival of new crafts and techniques...but the Sultanate’s success in collecting a heavy land tax on a centralize­d basis also contribute­d to creating the basis for urban expansion…” The real significan­ce of this statement is that students of political economy should always attempt to establish an organic relationsh­ip between the role of “the state” and the developmen­t of “economy” in society.

The negative side of this historical period, however, is that “…one can speak of urban growth in our period as a process that was partly parasitic in nature, flourishin­g on resources drained from the countrysid­e”. Slavery was rampant in the urban population in this period and this slavery contribute­d to the creation of surplus value for manufactur­ers and traders. The author mentions that towns consisted of multiple classes like slaves, labourers, merchants and a “state-generated middle class” besides soldiers and other functionar­ies of the king. Alauddin Khilji employed as many as 70,000 workers on his buildings, mosques, towns and forts and excavation of tanks. Huge building expansion programmes were also made possible by what “amounted to a technologi­cal revolution in the sphere of building constructi­on”.

The sack of Delhi by Timur in 1398 saw the centralise­d state replaced by small states in which local landed magnates, zamindars and many governors exercised their authority over the people living in their territorie­s. However, the Lodi Dynasty (1451-1526) re-establishe­d the Sultanate and some of its economy on the eve of the Mughal invasion in 1526, but the story shifts to the south, especially Vijayanaga­r, a separate state beginning with 1346.

Under Sikandar Lodi (1489-1517) the land tax was a major burden for the peasants but towns in the provinces that were transforme­d into independen­t principali­ties flourished, so much so that Babur (1526-1530) said of India that a “large manufactur­ing sector coexisted with an extensive network of credit and trade”. In the southern state of Vijayanaga­r “trade in the … empire was open to all foreigners.”

The contempora­ry message of this book is that colonisers came to “rob” India because they found a prosperous, growing economy. The study disproves the claims of colonial powers that they “civilised” India because the author clearly shows that the so-called uncivilise­d Indians were actively engaged in a highly productive economy when the colonisers came to plunder the country. The Period of the Delhi Sultanate and the Vijayanaga­ra Empire Irfan Habib Tulika Books; 250 pages; ~280

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India