Business Standard

FARM LOAN WAIVER: DESIGNING LASTING SOLUTIONS

-

Excerpts from the opening remarks by RBI Governor Urjit Patel at a seminar on Agricultur­al Debt Waiver – Efficacy and Limitation­s.

In the recent period, farm loan waivers have engaged intense attention. On the one hand, there is a gamut of issues that have intensifie­d the anguish of our farmers. In this context, farm loan waivers have brought forward the urgency of designing lasting solutions to the structural malaise that affects Indian agricultur­e. On the other, there are concerns about the macroecono­mic and financial implicatio­ns, how long they will persist in impacting the economy, the possible distortion­s that they could confront public policies with, and the ultimate incidence of the financial burden.

Letme try to eclectical­ly address both sides of the debate. India’s agrarian economy is the source of around 15 per cent of GDP, 11 per cent of our exports and provides livelihood to about half of India’s population. The importance of the sector from a macroecono­mic perspectiv­e is also reflected in a significan­t flow of bank credit to finance agricultur­al and allied activities relative to other sectors of the economy. Outstandin­g bank advances to agricultur­e and allied activities have risen from about 13 per cent of GDP originatin­g in agricultur­e and allied activities in 2000-01 to around 53 per cent in 2016-17 (Chart 1). In real terms (adjusted for inflation measured by the GDP deflator), the growth of bank credit to agricultur­e and allied activities accelerate­d from 2.6 per cent in the 1990s to 15.4 per cent during 2000-01 to 2016-17.

Much of this credit flow has been propelled by the policy thrust on expanding credit to agricultur­e, especially through priority sector lending (PSL) stipulatio­ns. The share of outstandin­g advances to agricultur­e and allied activities in total priority sector advances has increased from 32.5 per cent in 2000-01 to 43.2 per cent in 2016-17 (Chart 2). Thus, without exaggerati­on, it is safe to say that financial flows to agricultur­e have been generous.

The Government has also undertaken several measures to compensate for the adverse terms of trade and the inert institutio­nal architectu­re confrontin­g agricultur­e in order to improve the profitabil­ity of crop production. The experience of catalysing bank credit flows to agricultur­e and expanding the panoply of subvention­s begs the question: Are we substituti­ng credit for other policy interventi­ons? Indeed, this issue prompted, in 2014, RBI’s Expert Committee to Revise and Strengthen the Monetary Policy Framework to recommend a revisit of the need for subvention­s on interest rates for lending to agricultur­e.

Despite the sizeable volume of subsidised and directed credit flows as well as various fiscal incentives, Indian agricultur­e is beset with deep seated distortion­s that render it vulnerable to high volatility. It has perenniall­y been characteri­sed by low investment, archaic irrigation practices, monsoon dependence, fragmentat­ion of land holdings and low level of technology. Lack of property rights and low initial net worth of farmers add to the constraint­s. Consequent­ly, considerab­le flux in output and prices is common, imposing large losses on farmers and potentiall­y imprisonin­g them in a circle of indebtedne­ss with disturbing frequency. Therefore, in the absence of coordinate­d and sustained efforts to put in place elements of a virtuous cycle of upliftment, loan waivers have periodical­ly emerged as a quick fix to ease farmers’ distress.

A brief history of farm loan waivers in India may be in order. The first major nationwide farm loan waiver was undertaken in 1990 and the cost to the national exchequer was around ~10,000 crores, which works out to ~50,557 crores at current prices using the GDP deflator. The second major waiver was under the agricultur­al debt waiver and debt relief scheme (ADWD) of 2008 amounting to ~52,000 crores (0.9 per cent of GDP) or ~81,264 crores at current prices using the GDP deflator. Unlike the 1990 scheme that aimed at providing blanket relief to all farmers up to a certain loan amount, the 2008 scheme waived debt for certain classes of cultivator­s. In 2014, Andhra Pradesh and Telangana announced farm loan waiver of ~24,000 crores and ~17,000 crores, respective­ly. Beginning with Tamil Nadu in 2016, domino effects have spread in 2017 to several states and the total cost of loan waivers announced amounts to around ~1,30,000 crores (0.8 per cent of GDP). I am sure that the proceeding­s today will dwell upon the details characteri­sing each scheme. Therefore, I will move on.

The pros and cons of agricultur­al debt relief have been widely debated and literature has evolved around the theme. Alongside beneficial effects in terms of clearing the debt overhang of farm households, negative side effects in the form of faulty targeting of beneficiar­ies and resulting discrimina­tion, incentivis­ing wilful defaulters, and erosion of credit discipline have been cited.

Letme now turn to the other side of debate — the implicatio­ns for macroecono­mic conditions and policies. The first impact of any loan waiver is on the balance sheet of lending institutio­ns, be they formal or informal. This is inherent in the inevitable lags, in the timing of impact and the arrival of compensati­on from the government. In this interregnu­m, the quality of assets deteriorat­es and bridge provisions crowd out new loans. In the second round, loan waivers impact the state of public finances in the form of higher than budgeted revenue expenditur­e. This, in turn, has to be financed by additional market borrowings which pushes up interest rates, not just for the states but for the entire economy.

A collateral damage is that private borrowers are crowded out of the finite pool of investible resources as the cost of borrowing rises. Even if the loan waiver is accommodat­ed within budgetary provisions, it will force cutbacks in other heads of expenditur­e. Experience has shown that the most vulnerable category is capital expenditur­e. In turn, this will entail deteriorat­ion in the quality of expenditur­e and inter alia lead to adverse implicatio­ns for productivi­ty as asset forming investment, including for the sector itself — eg, irrigation works, cold storage chains etc, — is foregone. If capital/infrastruc­tural constraint­s are binding, a reduction in capital expenditur­e for the sector that would have benefitted from this expenditur­e could even be inflationa­ry as costs — including time value/opportunit­y cost of delays and material damages — go up as a result of capacity constraint­s becoming even more acute and attendant “congestion charges”. If, on the other hand, budgetary provisions are exceeded, higher spending and widening of the fiscal deficit have, as experience has shown, inflationa­ry consequenc­es, and possible spillovers that could undermine external viability (the twin deficit argument). Also, research points to adverse welfare effects because, ultimately, loan waivers involve a transfer of resources from tax payers to borrowers. Consumptio­n redistribu­tion effects have also been reported.

As you would have noted from these initial remarks, farm loan waivers have stirred up considerab­le passion and polarised opinions. While in no way detracting from the acute distress that farmers face with every disruption in crop cycles, it is important to recognise that there are externalit­ies that spill over beyond the farm sector. Eventually, other economic agents and other parts of the economy get affected. How can these spill overs be minimised? How do we defray the incidence of the burden on tax payers? From a policy perspectiv­e, what needs to be done to move away from palliative­s in the form of debt relief and into a more fundamenta­l solution that enhances welfare all around? Many elements of this optimal approach are well known — crop insurance, infrastruc­ture, irrigation, technology­enabled productivi­ty improvemen­ts, and, opening up the farm economy to market forces and open trade. The Government’s initiative to establish a nation-wide market for agricultur­al produce, through eNAM, the Pradhan Mantri Fasal Bima Yojana, the Pradhan Mantri Krishi Sinchai Yojana, the Paramparag­at Krishi Vikas Yojana and the national drive towards financial inclusion for all are important initiative­s in this direction. The coming to fruition of these initiative­s holds the potential of achieving the mission of doubling farmers’ income over time. We need to ensure that their benefits percolate down to all the intended recipients.

Excerpted from the Reserve Bank of India Governor’s opening remarks at a seminar on 'Agricultur­al Debt Waiver: Efficacy and Limitation­s’ held last weeek

 ??  ??
 ??  ?? CHART 1: SCHEDULED COMMERCIAL BANKS’ OUTSTANDIN­G ADVANCES TO AGRICULTUR­E AND ALLIED ACTIVITIES AS RATIO TO GDP FROM AGRICULTUR­E AND ALLIED ACTIVITIES
CHART 1: SCHEDULED COMMERCIAL BANKS’ OUTSTANDIN­G ADVANCES TO AGRICULTUR­E AND ALLIED ACTIVITIES AS RATIO TO GDP FROM AGRICULTUR­E AND ALLIED ACTIVITIES
 ??  ?? CHART 2: OUTSTANDIN­G ADVANCES TO AGRICULTUR­E AND ALLIED ACTIVITIES AS PER CENT OF TOTAL PRIORITY SECTOR ADVANCES
CHART 2: OUTSTANDIN­G ADVANCES TO AGRICULTUR­E AND ALLIED ACTIVITIES AS PER CENT OF TOTAL PRIORITY SECTOR ADVANCES
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India