Business Standard

Why farmers march

- SHREEKANT SAMBRANI The writer is the founder-director of the Institute of Rural Management, Anand

Only something truly extraordin­ary could impress the media usually consumed by politics, elections and scandals of various sorts. Some 30,000 people walking along a busy highway the last week has been that blue-moon event. The Akhil Bharatiya Kisan Sabha march of farmers from Nashik to Mumbai is unique not just because of its size or endurance but also its peaceful and non-disruptive nature, not normally associated with such demonstrat­ions. Its leader, Dr Ashok Dhawale, has displayed dignity and maturity in his interviews, in sharp contrast with the fiery orations accompanyi­ng most mass mobilisati­ons.

The marchers are demanding complete loan waiver (Maharashtr­a has a partial one) as also of water and power charges, minimum support prices 50 per cent higher than costs of production for all crops as recommende­d by the National Commission on Farmers chaired by Dr M S Swaminatha­n, compensati­on for the damage caused by recent hailstorm and pink bollworm attack, and implementa­tion of the Forest Rights Act.

Why do farmers in Maharashtr­a (and those in Rajasthan, Madhya Pradesh, Tamil Nadu and Gujarat recently) turn to the government with such omnibus demands? Simple answer: They consider the government to be the default agency of the first and last resort, and not without reason.

Government­s, both central and state, have been acutely aware of the need to bring about changes in rural India as a prerequisi­te of developmen­t. The Second Five Year Plan (1956-61) brought agricultur­e into the ambit of the planning processes, which has continued ever since. Thus, the government became the agency to break the rural poverty logjam. Its efforts have produced mixed results so far.

The government strategy was to reduce the vulnerabil­ity of agricultur­e through irrigation, improving productivi­ty through better seeds, applicatio­n of fertiliser­s and pesticides and advice, greater and easier availabili­ty of farm credit, and later, market support, promotion of diversific­ation and coverage of risks. Providing relief became the overriding considerat­ion when droughts struck (196566, 1972, 1974, 1986, 2003, 2009, 2014 and 2015, to list the most significan­t such occurrence­s). Farmer suicides highlight both the misery and the need to provide immediate succour.

Both major irrigation and crop productivi­ty enhancemen­t (commonly called the Green Revolution) achieved commendabl­e results in their initial phases. But they suffered from limitation­s as well: Not being accompanie­d by localised effective water harvesting and use programmes in case of irrigation and being selective in crops and regions in case of the Green Revolution. The spread of hybrid vegetable varieties and gene-modified Bt cotton of the last two decades still leaves dryland crops such as pulses, oilseeds and coarse grains uncovered. Income from them fluctuates, condemning vast sections of peasantry to vulnerable positions.

The impact of government interventi­on in asset creation/rejuvenati­on and diversific­ation has been at best one-off: Production and productivi­ty moved from one equilibriu­m to another, higher one, but still on a plateau. The vicious circle shifted to a higher level, but was not broken and a virtuous one did not replace it.

Most agricultur­e developmen­t programmes aim at poverty eliminatio­n. They must move from relief to longer-term livelihood restructur­ing. Confucius said that he gave a hungry man a piece of fish, which satisfied his hunger for a day. Teaching him how to fish would have taken care of him for life. Augmenting assets to enhance their productivi­ty, education and skills training to improve employabil­ity on a sustained basis, all attack factors that cause poverty and attempt to break the poverty trap. They teach the man how to fish and hopefully, provide him a fishing tackle.

Average farmers are barely able to cope with their survival concerns. They can hardly be expected to mount an effort to make a significan­t impact on the constellat­ion of factors responsibl­e for the vicious circle. Even those with better resources would find such enterprise daunting. Consider this: You have inherited a decrepit property, whose rental does not pay for even the minimum maintenanc­e. You realise you need to invest effort and money to upgrade it, but would you do so? Farmers are no fools to invest resources they do not have into what they know is a losing propositio­n.

Yet they cannot suffer in silence. Their cry for succour is all-inclusive in its scope and addressed to the only earthly authority they know: Mai-baap Sarkar. The government usually responds by doling out palliative­s, rather than systemic remedies.

Rural distress has seldom registered on urban conscience. This writer was invited to deliver a lecture on the political economy of Indian peasantry a couple of months ago to a highly educated, knowledgea­ble and sensitive audience. The common refrain of all the comments at the end of the lecture was “we never knew all this!”

The current protest may not break the rural vicious circle, but it has made India more aware of Bharat’s distress. E P Unny’s pocket cartoon ( The Indian Express, March 12, 2018) has a telling speech bubble: “I am a farmer. May I gherao your attention please?”

That is an achievemen­t of sorts of the long march from Nashik, but it still has miles to go.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India