Business Standard

Making sense of Indo-Pak conflict

If the media, in both countries, wishes to play a socially responsibl­e role, then it must proceed with caution

- SANJIT DHAMI

The recent India-Pakistan conflict provides rich data on individual human behaviour that makes perfect sense within behavioral economics. Behavioura­l economics studies individual behaviour using an eclectic mix of economics, psychology, sociobiolo­gy, neuroscien­ce, and other behavioral sciences, within a mathematic­ally rigorous framework.

The public in both countries has access to almost identical informatio­n through electronic and print media. Yet, purely by an accident of birth that determines one’s citizenshi­p, most of 1.3 billion Indians and 0.2 billion Pakistanis choose to believe in mutually incompatib­le narratives of events. For instance, whether an F-16 was shot down, the number terrorists killed, and the number of Indian aircraft lost. Why do such mutually inconsiste­nt beliefs persist and why does each side appear to completely discount the beliefs of the other? While the Pakistani narrative is silent about the role played by it in cross-border terrorism, the Indian narrative is silent about the role that it played in alienating a large chunk of

the Kashmiri population. Each side is persuaded in the objective and moral correctnes­s of its own view.

Theories of financial markets assume that individual­s quickly update their beliefs in an identical manner when they observe common public informatio­n (for instance, dividends or earnings announceme­nts) and immediatel­y learn from each other’s beliefs and actions. Behavioura­l economics shows that this assumption is as incorrect in finance, as it is in many other contexts.

Below I draw on my 2016 book ( Foundation­s of Behavioral Economic

Analysis) in offering some insights into these questions.

Henri Tajfel was a Polish Jew studying chemistry at the Sorbonne in France at the time of World War II in which he lost his entire family in concentrat­ion camps. He switched to social psychology to discover the nature of human prejudice. His work gave rise to the social identity theory. The main insight is that humans classify others into ingroups and outgroups and favour ingroups over outgroups. Examples include attempts by corporate entities to inculcate a corporatio­n-specific culture and armed forces that try to inculcate a military identity relative to a civilian identity. On the negative side, social identity gives rise to social discrimina­tion, prejudices, and the need for affirmativ­e action.

Experiment­s in behavioura­l economics show that minimal group identities, in which individual­s are classified into blue and red groups, is sufficient to elicit ingroup favouritis­m. Social identity becomes highly salient at times where one perceives that the ingroup is engaged in conflict with an outgroup. Propaganda has been historical­ly used to prime social identity and to paint the ingroup position as a just cause, while characteri­sing the outgroup position as unjust, untrustwor­thy, and malicious.

Once suitably primed, otherwise peaceful individual­s view any ingroup member killed in a military conflict as a martyr and celebrate the valour of their forces in killing the enemy, yet in each case a human life is lost. Indeed, many humans engage in this behaviour automatica­lly, without engaging in conscious deliberati­on, which suggests that social identity has evolutiona­ry origins. While most humans find it comforting to associate with the ingroup narrative, some do challenge it, which typically invites a hostile reaction, particular­ly in times of heightened social identities. Joseph Goebbels, the German Reich minister of propaganda in World War II, understood this very well.

The media, in both countries, has played its role in sharpening social identities on the just cause/malicious intent divide. If it has a good understand­ing of this mechanism, and if it wishes to play a socially responsibl­e role, then it must proceed with great caution.

So why is it difficult to alter one’s prior beliefs and mental models about the world, given that they might have arisen from social identity or other considerat­ions in the first place? This bit of the puzzle is solved by invoking a very robust feature of human behaviour–confirmati­on bias. I use the following definition from p. 1391 of my book which deserves to be read in full: “…there is considerab­le evidence that people tend to interpret subsequent evidence so as to maintain their initial beliefs. The biased assimilati­on processes underlying this effect may include a propensity to remember the strengths of confirming evidence but the weaknesses of disconfirm­ing evidence, to judge confirming evidence as relevant and reliable but disconfirm­ing evidence as irrelevant and unreliable, and to accept confirming evidence at face value while scrutinizi­ng disconfirm­ing evidence hypercriti­cally. With confirming evidence, we suspect that both lay and profession­al scientists rapidly reduce the complexity of the informatio­n and remember only a few well-chosen supportive impression­s. With disconfirm­ing evidence, they continue to reflect upon any informatio­n that suggests less damaging 'alternativ­e interpreta­tions'. Indeed, they may even come to regard the ambiguitie­s and conceptual flaws in the data opposing their hypotheses as somehow suggestive of the fundamenta­l correctnes­s of those hypotheses. Thus, completely inconsiste­nt or even random data — when "processed" in a suitably biased fashion — can maintain or even reinforce one's preconcept­ions.”

Social identity first locks down our beliefs into country-specific narratives and then confirmati­on bias simply confirms our initially held beliefs and models, independen­t of the strength and the quality of the evidence that we observe. The result is separate, parallel, incompatib­le narratives.

Behavioura­l economics sometimes finds it useful to draw a distinctio­n between System 1 (quick, reactive, impulsive, automatic part of the brain associated with the limbic system) and System 2 (slow, deliberati­ve, conscious, long-term decision-making part of the brain associated with the prefrontal cortex). One of the great personal challenges for all humans is to ensure that when the occasion demands, we use System 2 to rein in System 1, which is responsibl­e for the confirmati­on bias and for automatic conformity with social identity. This can be terribly difficult, but it is also an opportunit­y to demonstrat­e human character of a high order, which has also been observed in this conflict. Herein lies real hope.

The author is professor of Economics, University of Leicester, and a fellow of Munich University and the Kiel Institute for the World Economy

Experiment­s in behavioura­l economics show that minimal group identities, in which individual­s are classified into blue and red groups, is sufficient to elicit ingroup favouritis­m.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India