Business Standard

Need restructur­ing, not bankruptcy

Most stressed lenders should go into restructur­ing with the IBC being its bedrock

- SNAKES & LADDERS AJAY SHAH The writer is an independen­t scholar

In India, we tend to think of debt that performs vs. debt that goes into the bankruptcy process. However, when there is stress in repayment, the first port of call should be a negotiatio­n that leads to debt restructur­ing. Restructur­ing [under the shadow of the Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code (IBC)] is the best of all worlds, and only a few irreconcil­able situations should slip into the bankruptcy code. Many features of the Indian institutio­nal landscape come in the way.

Suppose there is debt with a net present value (NPV) of ~100. Suppose the firm gets into trouble and this debt is unlikely to be repaid. One vision of the world emphasises the IBC. If you can’t pay on your debts, the lenders will eject the shareholde­rs, and get whatever is the residual value of the company. Suppose this residual value is ~40. It is absolutely essential, in building the institutio­nal apparatus of a market economy, for lenders to have this power.

But it is not in the best commercial interests of the lenders to always rely on the bankruptcy code. When they get ~40 through the IBC, they still have a loss of ~60. Is there a possibilit­y of doing better? On one extreme is the number ~100, which the shareholde­rs refuse to pay. At the other extreme is the number ~40 that the IBC process can generate — which is a big loss for the lenders. Is there a deal to be found in between? This is the question of restructur­ing.

The bankruptcy process ejects the shareholde­rs (who know a lot about the company) and imposes a disruption on the firm. It involves paying a lot of money to lawyers, accountant­s, and consultant­s. All this induces “bankruptcy costs”. If the shareholde­rs and lenders can find a negotiated solution, these bankruptcy costs are eliminated.

Roughly speaking, a good solution is the combinatio­n of a write-down of debt by the lenders, coupled with a rights issue. Suppose an agreement is reached where the lenders will get ~75 on an NPV basis. This cuts their loss from ~60 to ~25. This is a much better deal — on paper. There is still risk in the picture, as the lenders are not sure that the restructur­ed debt will actually perform. Alongside this, the shareholde­rs do a rights issue, through which they bring in ~20. This serves two purposes. First, the shareholde­rs show their commitment to the lenders, and they signal their belief that the business is truly sound and can be salvaged. Second, they contribute to making the firm financiall­y healthy and increase the chances that the promised ~75 of repayment will work out. For the shareholde­rs, they get to retain control of the company they know well, for a price of ~20, as distinct from being forced out by the IBC.

This is the rough depiction of a good deal in debt restructur­ing. If the incumbent shareholde­rs don’t believe in the company, the IBC is the best answer. If they believe they can make it work, they should prove their commitment by doing a rights issue. The lenders should accept a write-down. The two moves (debt reduction plus equity infusion) will add up to a healthier firm and a fresh start for the company as a going concern. This negotiatio­n avoids the legal complexiti­es of the IBC but it can take place only under its shadow. In some sense, the very purpose of the IBC is to create the threat through which the shareholde­rs are brought to the table for such a negotiatio­n.

In this example, the lenders got to a loss of ~25 through restructur­ing while the IBC process would have generated a loss of ~60. The difference (~35) is the bankruptcy cost. It represents the needless value destructio­n imposed by an inflexible society that is not able to negotiate and find good deals.

In India, we often think finance can be reduced to a bureaucrac­y, decisions can be made through fixed formulas, or central plans can be made by regulators. The essence of finance, however, is imprecise informatio­n, speculativ­e forecasts based on incomplete informatio­n, judgement, and risk-taking. There are no objective formulae that can determine the numerical values of this article for any specific realworld situation. Discoverin­g these numbers requires organisati­onal capital. These values unfold through staff working in complex financial firms that know how to obtain informatio­n, do research, exercise judgement, engage in negotiatio­n, and make deals. There is no role for the judiciary, legislatur­e, executive, or regulator in any of this.

In a sensible arrangemen­t, most stressed lenders should go into restructur­ing, and the role of the IBC is to create conditions for the negotiatio­n and to mop up the cases where the negotiatio­n fails. Many features of the Indian institutio­nal landscape come in the way. Banking regulation hampers both restructur­ing and the IBC. Sound banking regulation would force banks to aggressive­ly write down stressed debt. In our example, the bank should be forced to write the debt down to a low value like ~25. Once this is done, the bank would have the right incentives to fight for the bankruptcy process (which gets to ~40, i.e. a profit of ~15) or the restructur­ing (which gets to ~75, i.e. a profit of ~50). If banking regulation collaborat­es with banks to portray stressed assets as being worth ~100, banks are reduced to approving loans and hoping for the best.

The second problem is the alignment of employees of lenders with the profit objectives of their organisati­ons. It is truly hard for financial firms to get their employees to work for the organisati­on. The individual­s in financial firms veer towards inaction, covering up, and corruption. The threat of investigat­ion by agencies and regulators, and their lack of rule of law procedures, create a climate of fear and interfere with the negotiatio­n.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ?? ILLUSTRATI­ON: AJAY MOHANTY ??
ILLUSTRATI­ON: AJAY MOHANTY

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India