Business Standard

A precarious pragmatism

Without the road map that an economic ideology provides, govt’s search for practical ways out of specific problems has led it to appear erratic and inconsiste­nt

- The writer is head of the Economy and Growth Programme at the Observer Research Foundation, New Delhi

Nobody can accuse the National Democratic Alliance government of having a coherent economic ideology. It is true that, prior to the 2014 election, hopes were raised that a Narendra Modi premiershi­p would be economical­ly reformist. And there certainly have been some major reforms in the past seven years, including in bankruptcy and indirect taxes. But there has also been some major backslidin­g, such as on trade and in statist industrial policy. Recent statements that suggest the government is willing to restart stalled trade negotiatio­ns — driven both by post-pandemic requiremen­ts and geopolitic­al pressures — are representa­tive of this incoherenc­e.

Policy has taken multiple, and sometimes contradict­ory, directions. The government on the one hand has restored the primacy of the public sector, and made it clear it wishes to continue to occupy the commanding heights of the economy; on the other hand, revenue considerat­ions have forced it to consider monetising the public sector’s assets. It has sought to avoid new trade agreements and shut down legacy investment agreements, while also claiming that it wishes to expand Indian export markets through subsidies and incentives. It has introduced methods to make paying taxes easier and “faceless”, while also expanding the scope for official capricious­ness against taxpayers, supposedly to combat evasion. It has backed big business against farmers on land acquisitio­n; small shopkeeper­s against big business on e-retail policy; and consumers against small shopkeeper­s on “hoarding” of essential commoditie­s. It has sought corporate foreign investment into the Indian economy, while also backing domestic companies against foreign-owned ones such as Amazon or Mastercard. As a solution to mass youth underemplo­yment, it has at various points promoted the “personal sector” or micro-entreprene­urship, “Make in India” or mass manufactur­ing employment, and public sector jobs. It has provided the Reserve Bank of India with a legal framework for monetary policy targeting and independen­ce, and then has sought to undermine the framework it itself provided through personnel selections and forcing the central bank into indirectly support of deficit financing. It has tried to cut down and rationalis­e centrally sponsored schemes to give states more room to set policy, and then it has tried to cramp states’ policy making through restrictiv­e terms of reference to the Finance Commission.

Objectivel­y, these add up to a government without the road map that an economic ideology provides neverthele­ss searching for practical ways out of specific problems. It does not suffer from inflexibil­ity, but it also has no staying power — and thus ends up appearing erratic and impulsive. Just as targets are no substitute for vision, this precarious pragmatism is no replacemen­t for consistenc­y and predictabi­lity. Pragmatism is a useful, even vital, quality for policy makers — especially in uncertain environmen­ts. But that very uncertaint­y also requires the sort of policy stability that comes from a coherent view of India’s economic trajectory and of how immediate problems fit into that trajectory.

One might argue that India’s two most problemati­c growth bottleneck­s are productivi­tyandinves­tment.yet,withoutapr­operlygrou­nded and integrated view of the world, the problems of manufactur­ing, of exports, of employment, of trade deficits, of stagnant wages, of fiscal space, of inflation, of aggregate demand and so on might all seem to be different and isolated, and requiring separate prescripti­ons. This is how the government has been treating them, and this is why there is incoherenc­e to its policy solutions. Trade deficits are being addressed by keeping us out of trade agreements and export promotion, with a cost to inflationa­ndproducti­vity;inflationi­scontrolle­dbymonetar­ypolicytar­geting,withaneffe­ctonrates,investment, and manufactur­ing; manufactur­ing is being addressed through incentive schemes, with a cost to the fisc; fiscal space is being eased through tax enforcemen­t and fuel taxes, with an effect on aggregate demand; aggregate demand is being addressed through deficits, with a consequent increase in inflationa­ry pressure; and so on.

If, instead, it is productivi­ty and investment that are the immediate bottleneck­s, then government effort should be focused on improving those two factors.

Productivi­ty can be addressed first by increasing the human capital available in the economy, and by ensuring that employers can tap it more easily. This requires more focused support for skilling; and support to migrant workers in order to allow individual­s to move to high-productivi­ty parts of the country. Search costs for employers and employees have to be reduced, and individual­s seeking to up-skill or move need a social welfare net to allow them to do so. Welfare schemes therefore have to be redesigned to aid in increasing India’s human capital. The second requiremen­t for productivi­ty gains is the right incentives and opportunit­ies for companies. They cannot hide behind government protection from competitio­n, or expect subsidies for unproducti­ve activity. Equally, they need to be free and able to make the hard choices in terms of financing, ownership, employment and location needed to become globally competitiv­e. They need access to better sources of finance than public sector banks; freedom to hire and fire; visibility in the future availabili­ty and pricing of inputs like electricit­y; and an open and deregulate­d land market.

Investment — which, remember, has recently hit lows not seen for decades — can be increased only through a coherent vision of where future demand will come from. Given current capacity, demand and growth prospects in the domestic economy, it is meaningles­s to expect investment to bump up only to serve Indian consumers. Any transitory increase in investment thanks to production-linked incentive schemes will only result in the creation of unproducti­ve and ultimately costly capacity. Nor is it likely that, in an economy suffering from overcapaci­ty and in which potential growth has sunk to 4-5 per cent a year, investment is likely to reach the levels seen in the 2000s. Thus augmenting domestic with global demand is necessary if investment is to go back up — which might in turn require a very different approach to trade agreements than hitherto. In addition, a sustained increase in private investment will require stability in tax policy, in regulatory policy, and greater speed and transparen­cy in dispute regulation — whether by independen­t regulators or by courts. It requires the government to not be a party to disputes — since investors know they cannot win against the Indian government — and thus a smaller public sector and fewer tax demands. The government might claim that this is not what the Indian industrial­ists it meets are asking for; they are asking for direct fiscal incentives or tariff walls. But it might also consider the effects of sample selection: the industrial­ists who survive and think they can grow in this environmen­t, and are on talking terms with the government, are precisely those who will be asking for direct fiscal incentives.

Pragmatism and flexibilit­y is a virtue. An untethered and short-term approach to policymaki­ng is a flaw. The government must try harder to find the former without losing its way towards the latter.

 ?? MIHIR S SHARMA ?? POLICY RULES
MIHIR S SHARMA POLICY RULES
 ?? Illustrati­on Ajay Mohanty ??
Illustrati­on Ajay Mohanty

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India