Business Standard

Assessing the case for a legal MSP

Greater clarity on its precise connotatio­n could help resolve the continuing standoff between the government and farmers

- MIHIR SHAH

The year-long standoff between the government and the farmers ended with the decision to repeal the three farm laws. However, there is now a new bone of contention: the demand for a legally guaranteed Minimum Support Price (MSP). To understand the thinking behind the demand, we must recognise the fact that due to characteri­stics unique to farming, market failure is rampant in agricultur­e. Which means that unregulate­d free markets throw up outcomes that are detrimenta­l to both farmers and consumers. The seasonalit­y of farm production means that the vast majority of farmers (who lack the resources to store their crop) come to the market at the same time. During a bumper harvest, while prices fall, the resulting rise in demand is not enough to salvage incomes, especially for those producing food crops. Being basic necessitie­s of life, the demand for food crops is typically price inelastic, which means consumers will not demand very much more, even when prices fall. And unlike industrial producers who can make profits even as prices fall, by cutting unit costs, in agricultur­e, uncertaint­ies of the weather and limitation­s of soil fertility and water availabili­ty imply that increasing returns to scale are very difficult to achieve for most farmers. Thus, in bumper harvests, farm revenues necessaril­y decline for the vast majority of India’s small and marginal farmers. Correspond­ingly, for poor consumers, unregulate­d markets for foodgrains mean that during a drought they either starve or get pauperised, being forced to buy very expensive commoditie­s, convenient­ly hoarded by traders.

This is precisely the reason why, to protect both farmers and consumers, the state has intervened in agricultur­al markets for at least 50 years now. The idea was that as farm output rises with the Green Revolution (GR), farmers must be assured that their surplus would be bought by the government at an MSP that is high enough to leave them a margin, after covering their costs. The crops procured were then made available to consumers at subsidised rates through the Public Distributi­on System (PDS). Thus, government interventi­on protected farmers during bumper crops and dipped into the buffer stock so developed to protect consumers during droughts.

The problem, however, is that the MSP regime has been narrowly focused on rice and wheat, and has worked in only a few regions of the country, covering a very small proportion of farmers. This is the impulse behind the demand for a legally guaranteed MSP.

It is argued that only a legal guarantee will ensure that the government walks its talk by actually procuring the crops for which it announces MSPS. In the absence of which, the announceme­nt of MSPS for 23 crops every year is reduced to a token ritual, with little benefit to most farmers. How many tribal areas and farmers, for example, are covered under the MSP regime?

There is also a powerful ecological and nutritiona­l case for the demand. Since the Green Revolution, India has moved towards a monocultur­al regime, which has greatly impaired resilience of farm systems in multiple ways. Around 90 per cent of India’s water is consumed in farming and of this 80 per cent is used up by rice, wheat and sugarcane. Farmers continue to grow these water-intensive crops even in water-short regions primarily because of an assured market — for rice and wheat in the form of public procuremen­t. This only aggravates the water crisis.

Cropping patterns need to be diversifie­d to include a variety of millets (rightly called “nutri-cereals” now), pulses and oilseeds, which are better suited to the agro-ecology of each region. To incentivis­e farmers to make this change, government­s must include them in procuremen­t operations. The locally procured crops should then be incorporat­ed into anganwadi supplement­ary nutrition and school mid-day meal programmes. This would mean a large and steady market for farmers, while also making a huge contributi­on to tackling India’s twin syndemic of malnutriti­on and diabetes, since these crops have a much lower glycemic index, while providing higher content of dietary fibre, vitamins, minerals, protein and antioxidan­ts.

The case for expanding and diversifyi­ng Msp-based public procuremen­t is, therefore, well-establishe­d. The only question is: what is the best route to achieving this goal? And what exactly do we mean by a legal MSP? Clearly if this were to imply nationalis­ation of farm trade, where the government buys all farm produce, it would be an unmitigate­d disaster. A punitive regime would be very hard to implement and end up becoming counterpro­ductive, with the possibilit­y that farmers may find no buyers if traders refuse to buy at the legal MSP.

The Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Act (MGNREGA) could provide some answers. An interventi­on in the labour market, which, left to its own devices, was resulting in terrible exploitati­on of the rural poor, the MGNREGA does not guarantee 365 days of work to every person who seeks work. The legal guarantee is for 100 days per family per year, around onetenth of the former. But even such a small interventi­on has resulted in the tightening of the labour market, with rural wages and livelihood security improving. Something very similar can be done through the 2018 PM-AASHA scheme, wherein 25 per cent of the production for the season is to be procured by the government (to be expanded up to 40 per cent, if the commodity is part of the PDS). The “deficit price payment” mechanism can also play a crucial role, where the government pays the farmer the gap between market prices and MSP. Thus, a legal MSP must be backed by a programme with requisite resources (like MGNREGA) and a time-frame within which government­s would expand and diversify their procuremen­t portfolios, in line with agro-ecology.

Of course, farmers and the government must recognise that merely reforming the MSP regime will not resolve the farm crisis. In a forthcomin­g paper in the journal Ecology, economy and Society, I have outlined multiple barriers to be dismantled, without which sustainabl­e prosperity will remain a distant dream for India’s farmers: correcting uneven regional distributi­on of investment­s, which has led to the neglect of India’s drylands; moving away from commodity-centric R&D towards a whole systems understand­ing of farming; altering the pattern of subsidies that is overwhelmi­ngly biased in favour of chemical inputs; taking the understand­ing of soils beyond narrow GR thinking; strengthen­ing the legal and regulatory framework governing chemical inputs; making massive investment­s in postharves­t infrastruc­ture to support safe and nutritious food; and bringing agricultur­e education out of the 50-yearold outmoded GR paradigm. It is my sincere hope that both the government and farmers, drawing the right lessons from the long experience of the Green Revolution, will work together to move India towards this new paradigm of agro-ecological farming.

The “deficit price payment” mechanism can also play a crucial role, where the government pays the farmer the gap between market prices and MSP

The writer is co-founder Samaj Pragati Sahayog, one of India’s largest grass-roots initiative­s for water and livelihood security, and Chair, National Coalition for Natural Farming

 ?? ??
 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India