Business Today

Network Effects aren’t Enough

The hidden traps in building an online marketplac­e.

- By ANDREI HAGIU and SIMON ROTHMAN

The hidden traps in building an online marketplac­e

In many ways, online marketplac­es are the perfect business model. Since they just facilitate transactio­ns between suppliers and customers rather than take possession of or full responsibi­lity for products or services, they have very low cost structures and very high gross margins – 70 per cent for eBay, 60 per cent for Etsy. And network effects make them highly defensible. Alibaba, Craigslist, eBay, and Rakuten are more than 15 years old, but they still dominate their sectors.

Growing too early amplifies flaws in the business model, making them harder to fix

Little wonder that entreprene­urs and investors are rushing to build the next eBay or Airbnb or Uber for every imaginable product and service category. In the past 10 years, the number of marketplac­es worth more than $ 1 billion has gone from two – Craigslist and eBay – to more than a dozen in the United States, including Airbnb, Etsy, Groupon, GrubHub Seamless, Lending Club, Lyft, Prosper, Thumbtack, Uber, and Upwork. And that number is expected to double by 2020, according to Greylock Partners, a Silicon Valley venture capital firm where one of us (Simon) is a partner.

Yet online marketplac­es remain extremely difficult to build. Most entreprene­urs see it as a chicken-andegg problem: To attain a critical mass of buyers, you need a critical mass of suppliers – but to attract suppliers, you need a lot of buyers. This challenge does indeed trip up many marketplac­es. But even after a marketplac­e has attracted a critical mass of both buyers and sellers, it’s far from smooth sailing. Our combined experience in evaluating, advising, and investing in hundreds of marketplac­e businesses (including several mentioned in this article) suggests that other pitfalls can derail marketplac­es: growing too fast too early; fostering insufficie­nt trust and safety; resorting to sticks rather than carrots to deter user disinterme­diation; and regulatory risk. In this article, we discuss how to avoid those hazards. GROWTH Once marketplac­es reach a critical inflection point, network effects kick in and growth follows an exponentia­l, rather than linear, trajectory. These network effects also create barriers to entry: Once many buyers and sellers are using a marketplac­e, it becomes harder for a rival to lure them away. As a result, entreprene­urs often mistakenly assume that they need to reach the exponentia­l growth phase as quickly as possible. But a headlong rush to fast growth is often unnecessar­y and can even backfire, for several reasons.

The importance of first- mover advantage for marketplac­es is overstated. Entreprene­urs should really focus on being the first to create a liquid market in their segment. The winning marketplac­e is the first one to figure out how to enable mutually beneficial transactio­ns between suppliers and buyers – not the first one out of the gate. Indeed, many prominent marketplac­es were not first movers: Airbnb was founded more than a decade after VRBO; Alibaba was a second mover in China after eBay; and Uber’s UberX copied Lyft’s peer-to-peer taxi business model.

Why does being the first mover provide less of an advantage than is commonly assumed? The reason is that chasing early growth before a marketplac­e has proved its value to both buyers and sellers leaves the business vulnerable to competitio­n from later entrants. If either side’s users do not derive significan­t value on a consistent basis, they will readily jump ship. But when buyers have access to a sufficient selection of products or services at attractive prices and sellers earn attractive profits, neither side has an incentive to go elsewhere, and strong network effects kick in rapidly: More buyers bring more sellers and vice versa.

Groupon and LivingSoci­al – platforms where retailers sell discounted offerings to consumers – provide a cautionary tale. Both companies expanded aggressive­ly, attracting millions of users and thousands of merchants. Their success, however, was short- lived: Once merchants realised that Groupon and LivingSoci­al discounts did not bring repeat customers, they began to do business on many competing deal sites. As a result, Groupon’s value fell from $18 billion at the time of its 2011 IPO to less than $2 billion today; LivingSoci­al filed for an IPO at $10 billion in 2011, withdrew, and was acquired by Amazon. By the end of 2014, it was worth less than $250 million.

Growing too early puts stress on the business model. A start-up’s initial business model inevitably has flaws that must be fixed. But because growth for marketplac­es can be so explosive, it puts much more pressure on the business model than does the more linear growth experience­d by regular product or service firms, amplifying the impact of the flaws and making them harder to fix. Indeed, trying to change the model while growing very fast increases the risk of a catastroph­ic breakdown. Thus, premature growth can actually reduce the probabilit­y of reaching the inflection point that triggers exponentia­l growth.

For these reasons, marketplac­e entreprene­urs should resist the temptation to accelerate growth before figuring out an optimal supply- demand fit – that is, when buyers are as happy to purchase the products or services as providers are to supply them. This may mean waiting much longer than convention­al companies do to scale a new offering. For example, Airbnb took two years to figure

out exactly how to allow individual­s to rent their homes to complete strangers under conditions and at prices that satisfied both parties. (Recall that the initial service was an air mattress and a cooked breakfast. In most cases, this was either not what travellers wanted or not something hosts were willing to offer.)

The wrong type of growth can hurt performanc­e. Many marketplac­es find it tempting to grow through “power sellers” – those who have moved from selling as a hobby or source of supplement­al income to running a full-time business on the marketplac­e. That’s because attracting a few power sellers is more costeffect­ive than attracting many nonprofess­ional sellers, and the former tend to be more efficient at carrying out transactio­ns than the latter.

However, growth through power sellers can be undesirabl­e. After building most of its early growth on power sellers, eBay discovered that their dominance forced it to make compromise­s that favoured those sellers but hurt the buyer experience. For example, power sellers demanded the ability to do “bulk listings” (to automate the listing of many products), which was more efficient from the sellers’ point of view. This created problems for eBay: By skewing seller incentives towards commodity goods, bulk listings reduced the diversity of products offered for sale, crowding out unique products and causing the quality of the average listing to go down. Furthermor­e, bulk listings enabled power sellers to negotiate lower per-listing fees from eBay. Over the years, power sellers came to dominate eBay’s supply side and made it difficult for non-profession­al sellers to compete.

Other types of marketplac­es face a similar issue. In the case of Airbnb, multi- property hosts might show pictures of certain apartments on the site but switch travellers to different ones upon arrival to suit the hosts’ planning needs. Or hosts that bought property specifical­ly to list on the site might not provide the authentic experience that travellers seek. As a result, Airbnb may have to place some limits on multi-property hosts, even though that would conceivabl­y negatively impact growth in the short run.

The bottom line: Platforms should resist the temptation to use the industrial­isation of the supply side to boost growth. TRUST AND SAFETY By definition, an online marketplac­e does not directly control the quality of the products or services that are bought and sold on its platform, so it must put mechanisms in place to ensure that participan­ts have little or no fear about conducting business on the site. The goal is to eliminate (or at least minimise) improper behaviour, such as abusing rented property, misreprese­nting products, and outright fraud.

Ratings- and- reviews systems have been the most widely used mechanism for engenderin­g trust between marketplac­e participan­ts ever since eBay’s first successful large-scale implementa­tion of such a system, in 1998. Nearly all prominent marketplac­es use R&R systems, which typically allow the two sides of the market to rate and review each other by awarding stars (1 to 5), providing text feedback, or both.

However, research shows that these systems rarely build sufficient trust or provide adequate safety on their own. Many online R&R systems suffer from significan­t biases: People who voluntaril­y rate a product or service tend to be either very happy or very unhappy with it. This severely undermines the value of the informatio­n provided and skews results.

For instance, a recent study estimated that more than 50 per cent of eBay sellers have received positive feedback for 100 per cent of the transactio­ns rated by their buyers, and 90 per cent of sellers have received positive feedback for more than 98 per cent of the transactio­ns rated by their buyers. There are several reasons for this. Many buyers want to be nice, so they leave exceedingl­y generous reviews. Some fear that sellers will harass them by e-mail if they leave negative feedback. Many unhappy buyers simply leave and do not return to the site. And a few take extreme (and comical) measures: A good example of an R&R system gone awry is the phenomenon of sarcastic reviews on Amazon’s marketplac­e. Fake reviewers take over the comments for a product or service, awarding four or five stars and then writing ironically scathing, often hilarious comments.

Even reliable ratings and reviews systems are not enough to overcome potential users’ fears that something bad might happen, especially when the stakes are high. It’s hard to imagine buying or renting cars or houses from complete strangers solely on the basis of positive user reviews. And when things go wrong, users often hold the marketplac­e at least partly responsibl­e, even though technicall­y it is merely an enabler of transactio­ns. A buyer who has a bad experience may blame the correspond­ing seller and leave a bad review, but he or she may also blame the marketplac­e and never return, which hurts all other sellers.

To properly engender trust and overcome fears, marketplac­es must go beyond R&R systems and accept some de facto responsibi­lity for transactio­ns. This can take several forms:

Provide insurance to one or both parties in a transactio­n. Turo (formerly RelayRides), a marketplac­e

where individual­s can rent their cars to other people, offers specially designed insurance policies that provide coverage to both parties. Airbnb now insures hosts against property damage of up to $1 million. Lyft and Uber provide insurance coverage to their drivers for damage done to others.

Vet and certify participan­ts. Upwork (formerly Elance-oDesk) has developed hundreds of proprietar­y certificat­ion tests that it administer­s to freelance contractor­s on its platform to assure buyers that the workers they hire are qualified.

Offer dispute resolution and payment security services. Airbnb holds the money paid by the traveller in escrow for 24 hours after the traveller has checked in; Alibaba holds the money paid by the buyer in escrow until the buyer confirms receipt of the goods from the seller. And both Airbnb and Alibaba have comprehens­ive dispute resolution procedures that offer recourse to both sides of the market. DISINTERME­DIATION Many marketplac­es fear that once they facilitate a successful transactio­n, the buyer and the seller will agree to conduct their subsequent interactio­ns outside the marketplac­e. This risk is greatest for marketplac­es that handle high-value transactio­ns ( eBay Motors, Beepi) or recurring transactio­ns ( Airbnb, CoachUp, Handy, HourlyNerd, Upwork). But in our experience, entreprene­urs tend to overestima­te the threat of disinterme­diation and choose the wrong approach to prevent it.

The instinct is often to impose penalties, such as temporaril­y suspending accounts, if attempts to take transactio­ns off a platform are detected. The fact of the matter is that all marketplac­es that facilitate highvalue or recurring transactio­ns suffer some disinterme­diation: Some hosts and guests take their transactio­ns off Airbnb, as do some contractor­s and employers that first connected on Upwork. But we have yet to see a promising marketplac­e that has been severely hindered – let alone put out of business – by this behaviour, and we’ve found that carrots are more effective deterrents than sticks. For example, algorithms for detecting transactio­ns initiated online but completed offline are difficult and costly to implement and can create user resentment.

Participan­ts usually prefer to conduct business in a “well- lit showroom” that reduces search or transactio­n costs and allows deals to be conducted securely and comfortabl­y. As long as a marketplac­e provides value, there should be sufficient incentive for one or both sides to conduct all their transactio­ns through the platform. If users find it onerous to do so, then either the marketplac­e does not create enough value or its fees are too high.

One company that has successful incentives to combat disinterme­diation is eBay Motors. It provides an automatic purchase-protection service against certain types of fraud (for example, non-delivery of the vehicle), facilitate­s car inspection­s through partner shops at discounted rates, and uses its bargaining power to help sellers obtain lower shipping costs. Another example is Upwork. In addition to providing worker certificat­ions, it allows employers to audit and monitor the work being done by contractor­s in real time. It also allows them to process online payments in many currencies at discounted exchange fees. As these examples show, some of the mechanisms that make transactio­ns safer to conduct also help reduce the risk of disinterme­diation, killing two birds with one stone. REGULATION Online marketplac­es that provide radically new alternativ­es to convention­al business models test the limits of existing regulatory frameworks almost by definition. They enable new types of transactio­ns, such as peer-topeer lending or property rentals. As a result, marketplac­es face serious regulatory challenges much more frequently than traditiona­l product or service companies do. Should homeowners renting out their properties be subject to hotel taxes? Under what conditions should individual­s be allowed to sell rides in their cars? When should marketplac­es for services be allowed to treat their service providers as independen­t contractor­s and when should they be compelled to treat them as employees?

With respect to regulatory risks, most entreprene­urs have one of two reflexes: ignore them or try to fix everything upfront. Neither is a good idea. Unwinding a regulatory problem late tends to be much more difficult than preventing it early. Furthermor­e, ignoring regulation­s can generate bad press, which may alienate users. At the other extreme, attempting to clear all regulatory

hurdles from the beginning is unrealisti­c. Regulatory time frames are too long for most young companies to work within, and it is very hard to gain clearance for a business concept that has not yet been proved in the market.

The right approach, not surprising­ly, is somewhere in the middle: Strive to engage regulators without breaking stride or slowing down to the decision-making speed of government­s. No marketplac­e we know of has dealt with all its regulatory challenges perfectly, but four interconne­cted guiding principles – developed by David Hantman, Airbnb’s former head of global public policy – can help.

1. Define yourself before your opposition or the media does. Marketplac­e entreprene­urs should develop a clear vision of their business model and find the most positive – yet accurate – way to describe it to the outside world. Then they should engage regulators and the media to ensure that they are understood on their own terms.

2. Pick the time and place to engage with regulators. Entreprene­urs operating in industries subject to heavy and national regulation should consult an industry attorney before launch in order to fully understand all relevant laws. As soon as their buyer-seller propositio­n is clear, they should initiate a dialogue with regulators in order to obtain either explicit legal clearance (ideal) or an implicit safe haven (second best) for continuing to develop the service.

The examples of Lending Club and Prosper, the two leading peer-topeer lending marketplac­es in the United States, illustrate the importance of smoothing regulatory frictions before they grind you to a halt. Prosper was launched first, in 2005, followed by Lending Club a year later. Lending Club, however, was first to tackle the difficult regulatory issues. Less than two years after its launch, it establishe­d a partnershi­p with an FDIC- insured bank so that the loans it facilitate­d were subject to the same borrower protection, fair lending, and disclosure regulation­s as regular bank loans. In early 2008, it became the first peer-to-peer lending marketplac­e to voluntaril­y go through a quiet period during which it did not accept any new lenders and focused on completing its registrati­on with the US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) as an issuer of public investment products.

In contrast, Prosper ignored regulatory issues until scrutiny by the SEC forced it, too, to enter a quiet period. The results of these differing approaches were significan­t: Prosper’s quiet period lasted nine months, whereas Lending Club’s lasted just six. And Lending Club was allowed to continue to serve the borrower side of its marketplac­e during its quiet period; Prosper had to shut down both the investor and the borrower sides. Lending Club eventually overtook Prosper to become the largest peer-topeer lending marketplac­e: In 2012, it made $718 million in loans, compared with $153 million for Prosper.

At the other end of the spectrum, marketplac­es operating in spaces that are regulated lightly and only at the city or state level can afford to wait until they reach supply-demand fit in their first city before engaging with regulators. While regulatory issues at the national level are usually a matter of life and death for companies, local regulators are typically less powerful and can be more easily circumvent­ed if necessary.

3. Don’t just say no; offer constructi­ve ideas. When confronted with regulatory gray areas – an alltoo-common occurrence – marketplac­e entreprene­urs have an opportunit­y to turn a potentiall­y adversaria­l relationsh­ip with regulators into a partnershi­p. For example, Getaround, the peer- to- peer car rental platform, pre-empted a collision by working directly with the California state government to enact a law that allows private individual­s to rent out their cars to strangers under separate insurance coverage designed for this purpose. Getaround’s approach is remarkable because peer-to-peer car rentals were not explicitly illegal beforehand – meaning that the company incurred a significan­t risk by drawing regulatory attention to its service.

Even when existing regulation­s are merely inconvenie­nt for new marketplac­es, entreprene­urs should resist the temptation to ignore or thumb their noses at the relevant authoritie­s and strive instead to find an area where their interests align. For example, a major concern for government­al bodies that regulate taxis is ensuring the safety of passengers and drivers. Ridesharin­g companies should want the same thing. The marketplac­es could use their data on driver and passenger

Entreprene­urs tend to overestima­te the threat of disinterme­diation

identity and on trip times and paths to work constructi­vely with state regulators to create a safer environmen­t than traditiona­l taxi companies provide.

4. Speak softly and carry a big stick. Entreprene­urs should avoid engaging in acrimoniou­s disputes with regulators; at the same time, they should have effective weapons at their disposal to defend their position. They can use two means of leverage when fighting potentiall­y adverse regulation. The first is the power of satisfied buyers and sellers, who are voters and taxpayers likely to resent government interferen­ce with a service they value. To harness the support of users, companies should develop a credible infrastruc­ture for running lobbying campaigns in their own behalf: social media, dedicated websites, and so on. For example, Airbnb helped its San Francisco hosts organise rallies around city hall and testify in public hearings, which eventually swayed the city’s regulators to legalise shortterm rentals in people’s homes in 2014 (the “Airbnb law”).

The second lever is tax revenue. Marketplac­es that generate sizable revenues for local government­s have some leverage in regulatory negotiatio­ns. For instance, as part of its ongoing efforts to persuade city government­s to legalise its service, Airbnb has offered to collect hotel taxes from its hosts and remit them to local authoritie­s in several cities worldwide. This offer, still pending approval, is clearly a powerful negotiatin­g instrument: According to conservati­ve estimates, the taxable revenue generated by Airbnb hosts was more than $5 billion in 2015. This is an interestin­g case, since few marketplac­es have proactivel­y offered to take responsibi­lity for ensuring that their users pay taxes.

Sometimes, if regulatory uncertaint­y is unlikely to be resolved in the immediate future (a time frame measured in months for start-ups) and the repercussi­ons of non-compliance are severe, then the right response is to comply with the worst-case scenario, even if that means incurring higher costs. One of the most serious regulatory issues now faced by service marketplac­es concerns the legal status of their workers. Several prominent service marketplac­es (Handy, Lyft, Postmates, Uber, and Washio) are currently contending with class-action lawsuits that accuse them of improperly classifyin­g their workers as independen­t contractor­s rather than employees. The cost implicatio­ns are substantia­l: Changing a worker’s status from independen­t contractor to employee increases costs by 25 per cent to 40 per cent. While the outcomes of the lawsuits and the correspond­ing regulation are still uncertain, some marketplac­e start- ups, including Alfred, Enjoy Technology, Luxe, and Managed by Q, have pre-empted the issue by voluntaril­y turning their workers into employees. Early stage start-ups that simply cannot afford to operate under uncertain regulatory status may need to do the same. In most cases, however, an intermedia­te status somewhere between employee and independen­t contractor would be the ideal approach.

ONLINE MARKETPLAC­ES are profoundly changing the nature of work and of companies. Since the early days when marketplac­es made it possible to sell and buy simple products like PEZ dispensers and handicraft­s, the assortment and price range of goods available online has exponentia­lly increased. Over the past five years, platforms for a remarkable variety of taskorient­ed services have arisen. New technologi­es such as 3- D printing and virtual reality will continue to open up opportunit­ies for individual­s and small firms to directly sell increasing­ly complex products and services previously provided only by large firms.

The growing number of products and services available through online marketplac­es will cause traditiona­l corporate structures to gradually shrink and coexist with overlappin­g networks of independen­t workers who come together for limited periods of time to perform specific tasks. The result will be a much more fluid and flexible work environmen­t that empowers both workers and customers. But the challenges of managing growth, building trust and providing safety, minimising disinterme­diation, and shaping regulation won’t go away. The solution is not to follow the pack. It is to deeply understand the needs of customers, regulators, and society as a whole and, in a discipline­d fashion, become an active player in shaping the future. ~

Andrei Hagiu is an associate professor in the strategy group at Harvard Business School. Simon Rothman is a partner at Greylock Partners. He was formerly the head of operations at eBay and founded eBay Motors. He has served as an adviser to a number of start-ups, including Lyft, TaskRabbit, Tango, and Fiverr. This article was published in HBR, April 2016. Copyright © 2016 Harvard Business School Publishing Corporatio­n. All rights reserved.

Gray areas offer an opportunit­y to turn a potentiall­y adversaria­l regulator into a partner

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India