FrontLine

C.P. Chandrasek­har: Dangers of falling rupee

The latest round of currency depreciati­on is likely to be scrutinise­d carefully as it portends a bubble economy that can burst.

-

THE rupee, which has been sliding in value for some time now, depreciate­d sharply in recent weeks, giving some cause for concern. The depreciati­on is largely against the rising dollar, relative to which its value has fallen by more than 7.5 per cent since the beginning of the year. The Reserve Bank of India’s reference rate, which stood at Rs.63.4 to the dollar on January 5, 2018, reached Rs.68.4 by May 24 2018 (see chart). Depreciati­on relative to other major currencies such as the British pound, the euro and the yen has been much less. Yet, the fall vis-a-vis the dollar is of significan­ce, especially since much of India’s trade and its foreign debt is denominate­d in dollars.

Discussion­s on the rupee’s decline, which is projected to continue, focus on its proximate determinan­ts. Prominent among these is the rise in the current account deficit on India’s balance of payments, intensifie­d by the recent sharp rise in the internatio­nal price of oil.

The current account deficit rose from $41.6 billion in 2016 to $73.3 billion in 2017. Further, the $23.2 billion deficit recorded in the last quarter of 2017 was significan­tly higher than that recorded in the previous July-september quarter ($14.4 billion) and in the last quarter of the previous year ($15.5 billion). The effects of this net outflow of foreign currency were enhanced by the retreat of investors because of rising interest rates in advanced countries and the still-hesitant recovery from the global recession.

There was a net outflow of portfolio investment­s of $8.44 billion in the January 1-May 25 period this year, with $7.95 billion flowing out in May alone. Since some of these trends are not triggered by developmen­ts internal to India, the problem is seen as not being India-specific, especially since the trends correspond to those in emerging markets across the world, with matters being far worse in countries such as Turkey and Argentina. While these proxim- ate explanatio­ns are indeed valid, the emphasis on them implicitly underplays what the tendency really reflects. Periodic bouts of rupee depreciati­on that sometimes even trigger panic are a symptom of India being a bubble economy. There are many features that warrant it being characteri­sed as one.

The first, and most obvious, is the fact that the purported success of liberalisi­ng “reform” lies not in the fact that India has been transforme­d, as intended, into an internatio­nally competitiv­e manufactur­ed-exports-driven economy, but in its emergence as a favoured destinatio­n for internatio­nal financial investors. The resulting large capital inflows have had a number of effects, all of which together define the bubble on which economic growth rides.

The inflows resulted in a medium-term spike in stock market values accompanie­d by significan­t volatility, with stock market valuations of many companies now at levels not warranted by potential earnings. Moreover, flows into debt markets have meant that India’s bond market—which was earlier restricted largely to government

bonds—is now seeing much activity in the corporate segment, adding to the exposure to foreign debt of firms looking to benefit from low interest rates abroad.

Since money borrowed at low interest rates in the advanced economies finances a large part of the foreign financial investment, and since borrowing by Indian corporates is at low interest rates, the level of capital inflows is extremely sensitive to the interest rate in the developed countries. If interest rates in the source countries were to rise because of changed circumstan­ces, new flows would dry up and investors may choose to book profits and exit. This could not only unwind equity and debt markets but also weaken the currency, making depreciati­on a reflection of the speculativ­e investment­s that preceded the tendency.

Large inflows of foreign capital, by enhancing liquidity in the system, also trigger a credit boom with increased lending to the private sector (both households and firms). It is such lending that spurs demand and drives domestic market growth. Since debt-financed consumptio­n and investment in this scenario is driven by the pressure exerted by excess liquidity on banks to increase lending, the chances are high that agents unable to service their debts will be drawn into the universe of borrowers. This increases the probabilit­y of default which, given the credit boom, can lead to systemic fragility. And such fragility can intensify the capital flight that generates exchange rate volatility.

Occurring in the context of import liberalisa­tion, the demand fuelled by debt is likely to be more import-intensive than would otherwise have been the case. Since liberalisa­tion in the case of countries like India does not substantia­lly enhance exports, the import-intensive consumptio­n and investment that accompany capital inflows generates a third source of potential pressure on the rupee in the form of a widening current account deficit. If the foreign exchange outflow on account of imports of goods and services and other payments to non-residents exceeds the inflows from exports of goods and services and remittance­s, the deficit, even if financed by capital inflows, sends out signals that the currency is vulnerable.

A country that cannot earn the foreign exchange needed to finance its current needs and must borrow to meet them is vulnerable to balance of payments difficulti­es and cannot sustain the value of its currency. However, until recently this problem was not visible because low oil prices had depressed and kept low the outflows on account of imports of goods. And when that was not true, capital inflows helped finance large deficits. That is changing now as oil prices have risen to $80 a barrel, breaching a number of “psychologi­cal barriers”. The reality that India is a country that is vulnerable on the balance of payments front is asserting itself.

In sum, liberalise­d trade and liberalise­d capital flows have substantia­lly enhanced India’s vulnerabil­ity, of which periodic episodes of currency depreciati­on are a symptom. Ironically, this tendency has been concealed by the large capital inflows spurred by liberalisa­tion and by the benefits that India derived from low oil prices. Both those advantages are now under threat as is the unsustaina­ble growth that capital flows and liquidity infusion stimulated.

INFLATION

Moreover, currency depreciati­on has effects that enhance pre-existing vulnerabil­ity. One form that takes is inflation. If trade liberalisa­tion has increased dependence on imports for consumptio­n and investment, depreciati­on by raising the rupee cost of imports would aggravate inflation. Since one of the factors underlying depreciati­on is an increase in the price of a universal intermedia­te like oil, the potential for inflation is much higher. Inasmuch as the proximate factors underlying the depreciati­on of the rupee also create an environmen­t where the growth generated becomes unsustaina­ble, the joint effect of those factors and depreciati­on is a tendency to stagflatio­n, or slow growth combined with inflation.

Inflation also forces the central bank to withdraw from the cheap money policies of the high liquidity years and raise interest rates. Since low interest rates are the only macroecono­mic instrument, howsoever effective, acceptable to neoliberal policymake­rs committed to fiscal austerity, the situation is one where there are no means to pull the economy out of the stagflatio­n that envelopes it.

There is one other developmen­t flowing from currency depreciati­on that can compound these difficulti­es. As noted earlier, an aspect of the surge in capital flows to markets like India is an increase in private foreign debt, as corporatio­ns seek to exploit the low interest rates prevailing in developed countries and the greater freedom to borrow abroad that liberalisa­tion provides. Since large capital inflows make the domestic currency appear strong, much of this borrowing in foreign currency is not hedged for possible losses stemming from any currency depreciati­on.

When depreciati­on actually occurs, however, the rupee costs of servicing foreign debt rise sharply. This is also the time when the stagflatio­n afflicting the economy hurts corporate profits, making the burden of servicing foreign debt too much to bear. The distress sale of assets that follows bankruptci­es results in asset price deflation, which worsens the problem. Depending on the intensity of these effects, the bubble can burst and the game of speculatio­n can unravel. It is for this reason that this round of currency depreciati­on is likely to be scrutinise­d carefully. It could be the round in which the bubble economy becomes unsustaina­ble.

When the rupee depreciate­s, the cost of servicing foreign debt rises sharply.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India