FrontLine

Price of disempower­ment

- BY SUKUMAR MURALIDHAR­AN

Growth is not the panacea it is held out to be because the truth is

a severely skewed distributi­on of wealth and resources is counteract­ing all growth potential in the economy, threatenin­g increased deprivatio­n for vast numbers of Indians.

AMID ALL THE ANXIETIES IN A TIME OF inflation came a moment of brief reassuranc­e, or at least the pretence of it. On May 12, the Ministry of Finance (MOF) issued a routine Monthly Economic Report, advising a “longer time horizon” in which to view the problem. According to this report, and contrary to lived experience, inflation during the past financial year ran lower than before. And all the current threats on the horizon could easily be mitigated through timely action by the government and the Reserve Bank of India (RBI).

Inflation over the year gone by, in the Mof’s assessment, had in fact a highly salutary impact. “Evidence on consumptio­n patterns”, it said, “suggests that inflation in India has a lesser impact on low-income strata than on high-income groups”. Indeed, the patterns of price inflation had “reinforced the favorable (sic) redistribu­tion of the income from top to bottom and middle-income group”.

Once seen as a worthy policy objective, redistribu­tion has for some decades been pushed down as a priority since it was seen as contrary to the efficiency imperative. The MOF now invokes the theme of redistribu­tion only to trivialise it.

The Consumer Expenditur­e Survey conducted in 2011-12 by the National Sample Survey (NSS) reveals the perfectly reasonable picture that the lower and middleinco­me groups devote most of their budgets to the broad category of “food and beverages”. Upper income groups in rural areas, too, share that trait, though the same income stratum in urban centres tends to spend the greater part of its budget on the broadly defined category of “refined core items”.

By plotting these expenditur­e patterns onto the rates of inflation applicable across commoditie­s, the MOF arrived at a measure of the “effective” hardship experience­d by various strata. The rates, it found, are significantly lower across all strata, but most so for the lower income groups, and least so for the top earners.

The MOF analysis came about a week after the RBI’S sharpest interest rate raise in many years. In announcing the move, which sent a spasm of anxiety through the markets and prompted a brief sell-off, the RBI governor spoke about the disproport­ionate impact inflation had on the poor. Clearly, he was going by common sense, with no prior intimation of the Mof’s research findings.

The weeks since end March, when the MOF concluded its research, have brought bad news. Time is in continuous flow, and people do not quite divide up their lived experience­s in accordance with accounting convention­s. Figures on inflation following the end of March indicate that the threshold of pain may soon be breached.

Redistribu­tion was recognised to serve a sound economic and political rationale under certain circumstan­ces. This was a key conceptual breakthrou­gh learnt in the bitter adversity of the global economic depression of the 1930s. But this wisdom, attributed convention­ally to the economist John Maynard Keynes, that public expenditur­e financed through progressiv­e taxation could contribute to the collective welfare, was buried in the 1980s when combating inflation became the singular focus of economic policy.

Underlying the war on inflation was the strategy that did not dare to speak itself out. As played out in its canonical form in the US and the UK, the effort to “whip inflation” was all about extinguish­ing the collective power of the organised working class. Decades of Keynesian full employment policy had created an uncomforta­ble parity in the bargaining power of capital and labour. And in a situation of declining competitiv­eness, a dilemma that the US and UK in particular faced, capital’s efforts at maintainin­g profitability by raising prices or slashing wages had little chance of success. The wage

price spiral had to be broken and that could be done only through a direct assault on union power.

HOW REAGAN FOUGHT INFLATION

A remedy for the unpreceden­ted situation of “stagflation”—high inflation coexisting with economic stagnation—came after a fashion from the US monetary authority, the Federal Reserve or Fed. In 1979, Paul Volcker was appointed chairman with a mandate endorsed by both Republican and Democrat parties, to fight inflation through all means necessary. He responded with a series of sharp increases in the interest rate between 1979 and 1981, sending the economy into a tailspin.

The 1980s began under the shadow of the “Volcker shock”, a brutal increase in interest rates that pushed the US into recession, propelling Ronald Reagan to a decisive win against the hapless incumbent, Jimmy Carter, in the 1980 presidenti­al election. And when Reagan brought his unique brand of “voodoo economics” to the mix, slashing taxes in the expectatio­n of an increase in revenue, and sharply raising defence expenditur­e to send the deficit soaring, interest rates went above a critical threshold, pushing nations around the globe, most so in South America and Africa, into a debt-induced meltdown. To rejoin the world of dollar-denominate­d global transactio­ns, these countries had to bid themselves down, devalue currencies and assume a lower position in the global value chain.

Inflation was squeezed out of the system as organised working classes in the West were coerced into surrender. Much of the developing world, under the threat of a breakdown of internatio­nal relations, chose the painful option of severe austerity. A modest man, Volcker in later years looked back on those years and was candid enough to concede that it was not the impersonal hand of economic policy, but the direct coercive power of politics, that was key in the fight against inflation. “The most important single action of the administra­tion in helping the anti-inflation fight,” he said later, “was in defeating the air traffic controller­s’ strike.”

The intent to defeat organised labour was clarified in August 1981, a few months into Reagan’s term as president, when 13,000 members of the largest air traffic controller­s’ union struck work. The US president did not pause to bargain or negotiate, as was the convention. He fired the striking workers, replacing them with military personnel. As job losses accelerate­d in the crunching recession that followed, corporate managers were permitted almost a clear field for dismissing workers in pursuit of capital restructur­ing.

Restoratio­n of the dominion of capital involved a shift towards finance. Capital was once associated with industrial production and technologi­cal creativity. From the 1980s onwards, it came to be equally about financial legerdemai­n. Countries across the world were invited to join the great financial boom that began in the 1980s. It was an alluring prospect but with severe downside risks obvious, most countries needed to be goaded into joining under debt-induced distress.

Agricultur­e was a constraint as India began its engagement with global economy. Output was not increasing at anything like the rate required to support the growth of manufactur­ing and services. And in terms of employment, agricultur­e continued to be the source of livelihood for the vast majority in the country. Allowing prices of agricultur­al commoditie­s to rise would conceivabl­y offer an incentive for higher production but would play havoc with living standards. How was that conundrum to be negotiated?

The question was taken out of India’s hands as the 1980s progressed, proving there were no half-measures in an engagement with global finance capital. It had to be either a total dissociati­on or a complete embrace. As debt accumulate­d and the economy threatened to melt down after a rude shock in internatio­nal oil prices in 1990, India eagerly embraced the pathway of globalisat­ion. From then on, there was no looking back.

India’s rescue package, negotiated with the IMF in 1991, required the curtailmen­t of subsidies deemed unproducti­ve. Removing these involved a rise in food prices through the early 1990s, unpreceden­ted in its severity. Household budgets were readjusted to deal with the new realities. But the erosion of living standards, particular­ly in rural areas, was apparent. A disastrous year of drought in 2002 accentuate­d the miseries, squeezing purchasing power still further. The story of distress is amply conveyed by the numbers: despite a sharp fall in food production, prices remained subdued, indicating that demand contractio­n in rural areas had counteract­ed the possible inflationary impact.

Political change in 2004 brought a shift in policy priorities. The introducti­on of the rural employment guarantee (subsequent­ly named for Mahatma Gandhi and now known as the MGNREGA) introduced a significant element of income support for the rural workforce. Economic buoyancy, caused in part by a rapid increase in portfolio capital inflows, supported government revenues through this phase of expansiona­ry fiscal policy. In 2008, with the global financial meltdown, the good times were at an end.

As the shock waves from the global crisis began to wash up on Indian shores, the government held firm to its expansiona­ry policy. In the next few years, the volumes of liquidity created through the boom years started flowing into commodity markets, creating another sharp rise in inflation.

“Financiali­sation” of commoditie­s is the term of art that describes this phenomenon of an imbalance between global flows of liquid money and the real economy. It is, if anything, a greater threat now, after the massive injections of liquidity to deal with the COVID-19 pandemic. For a while, the final destinatio­n of all the loose cash was the stock market, which enjoyed a seemingly endless boom despite the pandemic-induced gloom. Now the money is seeking out returns in commoditie­s. And the inflationary pressures are aggravated by supply-side bottleneck­s.

The integratio­n of the vast labour forces from India and China into the global economy had a major role in the “great moderation”, as the years of growth and low inflation that ended in 2008 are known. But this integratio­n, at least in the case of India, was never complete. Indeed, most employment growth in those years occurred in the informal sector, where workers have little job security or social protection. Holding down the protection­s that are regarded as essential in a modern economy was key to suppressin­g inflation through all those years. And so, too, were the vast movements that took place through the years of growth, as workers migrated in search of opportunit­y.

INTERNAL MIGRATIONS

Since the early years of the 20th century, the decennial census has recorded the magnitude of internal migrations. The figures are clear in their broad details. In the first decade of the 21st century, India’s population was mobile like never before. That reading is consistent with the unpreceden­ted record of economic growth through the decade. The 2001 Census recorded a migrant population of 314 million, just over 30 per cent of the total at the time, a proportion virtually unchanged since 1971. The 2011 Census showed a significant departure: over 455 million, or 38 per cent of the total population, reported themselves as migrants that year.

The 2021 Census operations, once postponed owing to the pandemic, will soon move into high gear. It will not quite be able to capture the magnitude of the mass reverse migration that happened between 2020 and 2021, since some of the migrants would conceivabl­y have returned to their places of work. During the years of the reverse movement, demand for rural employment under the MGNREGA increased substantia­lly, relieving some of the immediate hardships. But from the last quarter of 2021 on, there has been a visible slump in the rural demand for both durables and items of mass consumptio­n. Alongside rising prices, this suggests a pincer movement on the living standards of the poorest.

It is a time when distributi­ve justice clearly needs to be restored to the agenda, though not in the farcical way of the Mof’s recent analysis of inflation’s impact. Growth is no longer the panacea, if it ever was. The reality today is that a severely skewed distributi­on of income and wealth is counteract­ing all the growth potential in the economy, holding up a prospect of growing deprivatio­n for vast numbers of Indians. Inflation was once suppressed by forcing a regime of austerity on the poorest, but that clearly is no longer a politicall­y feasible option. m Sukumar Muralidhar­an teaches in the school of journalism, O.P. Jindal Global University, Sonipat. Views are personal.

 ?? ?? SUMITRA DAS inside her kirana shop in Talit Daspara, Burdwan, West Bengal, which she had to shut down as she could not afford to buy the stock anymore. From the last quarter of 2021 onwards, there has been a visible slump in the rural demand for both durables and items of mass consumptio­n.
SUMITRA DAS inside her kirana shop in Talit Daspara, Burdwan, West Bengal, which she had to shut down as she could not afford to buy the stock anymore. From the last quarter of 2021 onwards, there has been a visible slump in the rural demand for both durables and items of mass consumptio­n.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India