FrontLine

Unfinished agenda

Amid renewed public chatter on bank privatisat­ion, it is time to remind neoliberal ideologues that criticism of public ownership of banking is misplaced.

-

The long-standing debate on whether India’s public sector banks should be privatised has resurfaced in recent days. Two articles, besides numerous statements from advocates of “reforms”, triggered this round of debate—one wittingly and the other, perhaps unwittingl­y.

The contributi­on that argued for immediate action in the form of privatisat­ion, which was presented at the India Policy Forum, was authored by the establishe­d and well-known economists Poonam Gupta and Arvind Panagariya, who have been closely engaged with Indian policymaki­ng in senior positions.

It makes a case for privatisat­ion of all public banks, except for State Bank of India, which is expected to take on the developmen­tal responsibi­lities that private banks are unlikely to shoulder, given the adverse implicatio­ns for margins and profitabil­ity.

The other is a research article authored by Snehal S. Herwadkar, Sonali Goel, and Rishuka Bansal, officers in the Department of Economic and Policy Research of the Reserve Bank of India, published in the RBI Bullic letin of August 2022, which was clearly part of the research output of the department and focussed on the performanc­e of public banks in India.

The bank denational­isation agenda was revived by Finance Minister Nirmala Sitharaman in her 2021 Budget speech, which announced plans to privatise two pub

sector banks and a general insurance company. Clearly, the India Policy Forum input was not satisfied by the ambition implicit in that promise.

RBI DOCUMENT

It appears to be a coincidenc­e that the research article from the RBI’S department was published at a time

when the debate on privatisat­ion was being rekindled. But the article received more attention than research output from the RBI usually gets, because it pointed to the important and even crucial role that the public banking system played in ensuring financial inclusion—by extending the reach of banking and increasing lending to previously neglected regions, sectors, and groups.

Referring to a core theme in the article by Gupta and Panagariya, the RBI researcher­s argued that while on pure profitabil­ity grounds private banks in India appear more efficient than public ones, public banks turn out to be more efficient when financial inclusion indicators are added to the objective function. Moreover, public banks, unlike private ones, are counter-cyclical in their lending behaviour, playing an important role in times of stress. Underlinin­g this multi-faceted role of public banks, the article called for both caution and gradualism when privatisin­g public banks, if it was contemplat­ed at all.

Even if not revelatory in terms of the evidence it collated, versions of which have already been highlighte­d by many authors for quite some time, the contributi­on from the RBI researcher­s was significan­t for having once more underlined the fact that the years since nationalis­ation of leading banks in India (14 in 1969 and another six in 1980) have seen the achievemen­t of the goals, the pursuit of which motivated bank nationalis­ation in the first place.

NATIONALIS­ATION HISTORY

In the years after Independen­ce, until 1969, besides creating one major public sector bank (State Bank of India) with developmen­tal priorities, by nationalis­ing Imperial Bank of India, the government directly and through the RBI attempted to cajole and persuade private banks to expand to underbanke­d spaces and take on developmen­tal responsibi­lities by sacrificin­g a small share of their margins. But that attempt was a complete failure. The lesson learned was that yield-seeking privately owned banks, in which equity infusion by the owners was a minuscule proportion of the public savings mobilised as deposits, were unlikely to take on any developmen­tal responsibi­lities.

Even by the mid-1960s, the agricultur­al sector, which accounted for a large share of gross domestic product (GDP) and employment, received less than 2 per cent of the advances of the scheduled commercial banks.

What is more, a significan­t share of advances of individual banks was being diverted to projects in which the private owners or directors on their boards had an interest.

It is this refusal of the private banks to be more inclusive in their operations and support the government’s efforts to accelerate developmen­t that necessitat­ed nationalis­ation and forced the government to take that route.

When recognisin­g the success of that policy, the assessment by the RBI researcher­s was that privatisat­ion or denational­isation would result in a setback on the financial inclusion front and damage the larger developmen­t agenda. It must be noted that the article was not making

AT A CANARA BANK LOAN MELA

in Hoskote, near Bengaluru, where hundreds of tractors and other items were distribute­d to farmers, in March 2005. a case against privatisat­ion, but for gradualism in implementa­tion, in keeping with the the Finance Minister’s announceme­nt. Yet the article was interprete­d by many as pointing to the erroneous nature of the policy direction the NDA government was clearly inclined to take, and which neoliberal reformists have backed.

Given this conflict between what the government is advocating and what the article’s argument and conclusion­s are, the attention the latter received troubled the senior management of the Central bank. In an unusual move, the RBI issued a clarificat­ion which repeated the caveat that “the views expressed in the article are those of the authors and do not represent the views of the Reserve Bank of India” and went on to quote sentences from the article to establish that even the authors were “of the view that instead of a big bang approach, a gradual approach as announced by the Government would result in better outcomes”.

Broad-based and inclusive credit delivery is a must for successful developmen­t.

This sensitivit­y to suggestion­s that the Central bank and the government are not on the same page is partly a reflection of the recognitio­n that the NDA government is keen on completing a process of banking liberalisa­tion heralded by the Narasimhan Committee reports of 1991 and 1998, by privatisin­g the banks that had been nationalis­ed starting 1969.

To give power to that policy inclinatio­n, Gupta and Panagariya reiterated most of the arguments that have over time been advanced to denational­ise and privatise the public banks. In the process, they convert the achievemen­t of many of the objectives of nationalis­ation into evidence of failure. One example is the

lower relative profitabil­ity of public as compared with private banks. Nationalis­ation was deemed necessary because the single-minded pursuit of profit by private banks precluded creating branches in underbanke­d areas that would be needed to provide small-sized loans to dispersed borrowers such as small peasants, who in any case are vulnerable to crop failure.

Not only are such branches considered unremunera­tive, banks do not prefer such lending because the higher transactio­n costs and risks associated with it makes it less profitable than commercial lending to businesses or retail lending to middle and upper-middle income borrowers. Yet, broad-based and inclusive credit delivery is a must for successful developmen­t. Public ownership of banks was seen as a way of ensuring it, and nationalis­ation did indeed deliver.

A second claim is that public ownership leads to distorted lending, with direction of credit to sectors and target population­s that are not just less profitable but also more prone to defaulting. Targeted lending to priority sectors by banks under public ownership is seen as having resulted in high levels of non-performing assets (NPAS) that eroded the ability of these banks to offer adequate credit to productive sectors.

Together with “excess” lending to government, this is seen as having

displaced profitable and safer lending to the private sector. What is underplaye­d in that reasoning is the fact that government policy has, in recent years, worked to divert public bank credit to the corporate sector with adverse consequenc­es. This included large credit packages for private or joint-sector infrastruc­ture projects from public banks.

Convention­ally, banks do not finance such projects because of the large investment­s required and the lower or absent profitabil­ity. Moreover, such investment­s are relatively illiquid, since finding buyers for securities associated with such projects is not easy.

On the other hand, they involve large gestation lags and tend to be riskier. For these reasons, banks that mobilise money from savers interested in instrument­s characteri­sed by shorter maturities, greater liquidity, and low risk, are averse to lending to such projects given the maturity and liquidity mismatches involved. Thus, specialise­d developmen­t banks were establishe­d to finance investment­s of this kind.

But since developmen­t banks in India faded away after liberalisa­tion and there was a persistent need for enhanced investment­s in infrastruc­ture, the government decided to use its ownership of public banks to get them to lend large sums to the corporate sector for infrastruc­tural projects.

In time many of these projects performed poorly. Despite much help in the form of restructur­ing of loans on extremely favourable terms, defaults could not be avoided, leading to a sharp spike in NPAS in the banking system.

CORPORATE NPAS

These NPAS were not on account of lending to the priority sector but on account of lending to corporates, in keeping with the needs created by neoliberal reforms. Rather than locate the large NPAS of recent years to these liberalisa­tion-linked developmen­ts, Gupta and Panagariya attribute it to public ownership to buttress the case for privatisat­ion.

Finally, public ownership of banks is seen as a remnant of the policy of “financial repression”, which controlled interest rates, regulated lending and securities investment­s, and restricted competitio­n between banks in order to prevent them from raising deposit rates to attract savers and from investing in higher-risk projects involving higher returns. This was seen as limiting savings and diverting investment away from the highest-yielding projects.

However, as revealed by multiple banking crises across the globe since financial deregulati­on began, especially the global financial crisis in 2008, the case for such deregulati­on and liberalisa­tion has taken a hit. That has not prevented neoliberal ideologues from advocating such “reforms”, however.

These aspects of the role of public banks and the failure or weaknesses of private banks possibly explain the fact that successive government­s with a neoliberal agenda have not been able to roll back nationalis­ation, even though the denational­isation and privatisat­ion campaign began around 30 years ago.

That fortuitous “failure” shows that the criticism of public ownership of banking is misplaced, and that policies of liberalisa­tion and deregulati­on have lost their legitimacy. It is not the officers of the RBI but those pushing for privatisat­ion who need to be reined in. m

 ?? ??
 ?? ??
 ?? ??
 ?? ?? OUTSIDE AN SBI BRANCH in Vizianagar­am. The government of India created SBI to take on the developmen­tal responsibi­lities that private banks are unlikely to shoulder.
OUTSIDE AN SBI BRANCH in Vizianagar­am. The government of India created SBI to take on the developmen­tal responsibi­lities that private banks are unlikely to shoulder.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India