Hindustan Times (East UP)

Farm reforms — how both sides faltered

While the Centre should have allowed a longer legislativ­e process, agitators should not have disrupted lives and caused inconvenie­nce to other citizens

- Letters@hindustant­imes.com SAKIB ALI /HINDUSTAN TIMES

Over the past fortnight, the agitation against the Centre’s agricultur­al reforms — led primarily by land-owning farmers of Punjab, but now supplement­ed by a range of other farmer groups — has assumed a political, economic and regional element. Irrespecti­ve of how the issue is eventually resolved, the protests throw open questions about the trajectory of India’s political economy and developmen­tal model, the role of the State and markets in a sector that employs the largest number of people in the country, Centre-state relations, and the future of politics in rural India in general but Punjab in particular.

But the issue has also highlighte­d the strengths and weaknesses of the two key actors involved in the issue — the government as well as the agitators. What have they done right, and where have they gone wrong?

Take the government first.

The Narendra Modi government — as this newspaper has argued — did well in turning the crisis presented by the pandemic into an opportunit­y for reform. Indeed, Indian economic policymaki­ng experience shows that it is in moments of crisis that reforms are most politicall­y feasible, giving room to government­s to challenge status quo. If it was not for the balance of payment crisis in 1991, it is doubtful if the PV Narasimha Rao-Manmohan Singh duo would have been able to push far-ranging and necessary reforms which liberalise­d India, integrated it with the world, boosted growth rates, unleashed the animal spirits in the private sector, expanded the middle-class, enriched the government through additional revenues leading to enhanced welfare spending, and lifted millions out of poverty.

But one sector which was largely immune to the trajectory of reforms was agricultur­e. No agricultur­al expert can today argue with any justificat­ion that status quo is tenable. The structural issues in Indian agricultur­e need not detain us here — but the mismatch between agricultur­e’s contributi­on to GDP and the number of people dependent on it is enough to show that urgent reforms were essential. And that is why the Modi government acted with the right intent in reframing how agricultur­al produce in the country can be procured and traded. It broke the monopoly of the mandi system, enabled greater interface between agricultur­e and industry by allowing structured corporate participat­ion, and increased the freedom and choices available to farmers. This has the potential of enhancing farm incomes, infusing more capital in the sector, enabling diversific­ation and possibly paving the path for the modernisat­ion of India’s rural economy.

But if it was right in its intent, as well as the overall substance of the law, the government faltered in building wider consensus around reforms.

Do remember that the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP)-led government has had a somewhat paradoxica­l relationsh­ip with farmers in general. On one hand, it has faced fierce opposition from a range of farmer groups on diverse issues — from its proposed amendment to the land acquisitio­n act to the demand to implement the MS Swaminatha­n Committee recommenda­tions on minimum support prices (MSPs). At the same time, through a range of policy measures — the PM-Kisan scheme which enables direct cash transfer to small and marginal farmers; the focus on rural India in terms of constructi­on of homes and toilets, and provision of gas cylinders; occasional promises of loan waiver in states which it is in power (Uttar Pradesh in 2017); a genuine attempt to boost agri-infrastruc­ture — it has also won the support of a large segment of farmers. So, in a sign of the heterogene­ity of farmers and their aspiration­s, it is useful to remember that while segments have been upset, others have also voted overwhelmi­ngly for the BJP in elections.

But the Centre should have recognised that precisely because of this heterogene­ity, there was a large constituen­cy which could be uncomforta­ble with reforms and had the strength to express it. And that is why the farm reforms should have been preceded by much wider consultati­on in the public sphere. The government’s big mistake was in not allowing the farm bills to go through the parliament­ary committee route — stakeholde­rs would have not only got a chance to express their views and concerns, but it would have added legitimacy to the process. And even if this meant some delay, the democratic participat­ion within the constituti­onal framework was worth it. The government also clearly underestim­ated the depth of anger, especially in Punjab, even though it was apparent that given the well-entrenched mandi system and the more widespread procuremen­t of produce at MSP in the state, resistance could be fierce. The Centre’s actions led to the perception of unilateral­ism and only alienated those sceptical of the reforms further, providing the ground for a sustained movement.

But what about the agitators? Irrespecti­ve of whether one agrees or disagrees with the farm reforms, there is no doubt that the farmers are within their rights to express their opposition to measures which they believe will hurt their economic interests. There is genuine apprehensi­on at being left to the mercy of market forces without adequate protection. Farm unions have also done a remarkable political job in spreading their message down to the ground, forcing the entirely spectrum of political actors in Punjab and now nationally to support their demands, and registerin­g their dissent. They have also built a remarkable coalition of diverse interests — though it is somewhat ironical to see those who would have been otherwise categorise­d as feudal elements in agricultur­e and Left farm unions and even economic liberals who have, in the past, argued for more openness in agricultur­e — come together because they oppose the BJP. This may be hypocrisy, but it is also clever politics.

But where the farmers have faltered is in the method and idiom of the protests.

Any interest group in a democracy has the right to oppose the government peacefully and through constituti­onal methods. But this cannot be at the cost of underminin­g the rights of fellow citizens. To gain leverage in negotiatio­ns with the State, protesters have been inflicting costs on society — by blocking highways and the right to free movement and disrupting supply chains and the right to trade. This has not only caused inconvenie­nce but also led to inflationa­ry consequenc­es, the brunt of which is borne by the poor. It is easy for protesters, when they are in the middle of a movement, to think they have the edge and underestim­ate the State. And while the context is entirely different, farm unions would do well to remember that the anti-Citizenshi­p (Amendment) Act protests eventually lost their moral high ground because of obstructio­nist tactics. The other big weakness of the movement is in its maximalist posture — of seeking nothing less than a repeal of the laws — instead of being open to compromise.

Indeed, it is only through this political process of negotiatio­n that both reforms can succeed and interests of those fearful of reforms can be safeguarde­d. Both the Indian State as well as dissenting citizens are on test.

 ??  ?? Any interest group in a democracy has the right to oppose the government peacefully and through constituti­onal methods. But this cannot be at the cost of underminin­g the rights of fellow citizens. To gain leverage in negotiatio­ns with the State, protesters have been inflicting costs on society
Any interest group in a democracy has the right to oppose the government peacefully and through constituti­onal methods. But this cannot be at the cost of underminin­g the rights of fellow citizens. To gain leverage in negotiatio­ns with the State, protesters have been inflicting costs on society
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India