Hindustan Times (East UP)

What farming needs: Risk mitigation

Its absence makes farmers less receptive to pro-market reforms which add to income uncertaint­y

- Shoumitro Chatterjee is assistant professor of economics, Pennsylvan­ia State University, and a visiting fellow at the Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi

At the heart of the debate on farm laws is the issue of the level of farm incomes. Income volatility is a key dimension important for farmers’ welfare, understand­ing their anxieties, and the success of a pro-market reform. The two main risks associated with farming are production risks and price risks. While production-related risks that come from weather, pests and disease are well understood, price risks induced by the market or policy are more subtle.

Market price realisatio­n of agricultur­al produce is usually uncertain. When sowing, farmers have to guess the price their crops will get after four or five months when harvest occurs. After sowing, they have limited ability to change their decision. Price risks are exacerbate­d by policy. India abruptly changes export restrictio­ns on crops like cotton and onion, often multiple times between sowing and harvest. Thus, farmers are unable to make informed decisions; when internatio­nal prices are too high, export bans also keep farmers from making a profit.

Globally, government­s provide farmers with various risk-mitigation instrument­s. In India, Pradhan Mantri Fasal Bima Yojna (PMFBY), the government’s crop insurance programme, deals only with production risks. It does not cover livestock. Enrollment remains low and operationa­l challenges leave much scope for improvemen­t.

To deal with price risk, the only real instrument that the government provides is procuremen­t at minimum support prices (MSPs). When available, farmers use it to the fullest. In the 1960s, before procuremen­t of paddy and wheat started, Punjab’s farmers grew many other crops like maize, bajra, pulses and oilseeds. Three decades of assured procuremen­t has turned it largely into a paddy-wheat producing state.

Farmers understand the environmen­tal costs of growing water-intensive crops. But they choose to grow these crops, as they minimise their ex-post risk, even if they don’t maximise their incomes or welfare of future generation­s.

When farmers don’t have access to public procuremen­t, they mitigate risk by sowing low-value low-risk crops conditiona­l on agro-ecology. Research has shown that India’s domestic market integratio­n has increased income volatility and induced farmers to switch to lowerrisk crops. Consider the flood-prone areas of Bihar, where paddy crops get damaged due to monsoons. In unintegrat­ed markets, this would increase local prices. Thus, farmer income, which is a product of prices and quantities, is stabilised. In integrated markets, a reduction in local production leads to inflow of paddy from neighbouri­ng regions keeping prices stable. This is good for consumers. However, farmer incomes decline as their production loss is not offset by a price increase.

A single instrument, procuremen­t at MSP, is being used to solve multiple problems — risk, remunerati­ve prices, and food security. However, it is not the best solution. It cannot be made universal, is operationa­lly challengin­g, and environmen­tally detrimenta­l. Therefore, India needs a better plan. What are the elements that we need to consider?

First, to provide immediate relief there is a need to strengthen PM-Kisan (and its state-specific variants), especially in states where there is no public procuremen­t. It should also be expanded to include landless farmers.

The second is the debate over removing various subsidies — MSP, power, fertiliser etc — and replacing it with an equivalent transfer. If the latter is done, then we must ensure that the basic PM-Kisan infrastruc­ture works, and be cognisant about whether distributi­on chains of key inputs work and are competitiv­e. The switch will, then, have greater acceptance. The production systems in Punjab and Haryana have gradually evolved as a response to the procuremen­t systems that the government implemente­d for three decades. Overnight reversal is hard. Thus, farmers must be compensate­d for policy induced adjustment costs. These compensati­ons will have environmen­tal benefits when farmers switch from paddy to other crops.

Third, to insure price-risk, we can consider a procedural­ly simple version of the Bhavantar scheme to compensate farmers for losses from market price crashes. A price monitoring and market intelligen­ce system is necessary for it to work. However, this should be a top-up over the basic income transfer to target extreme events. If government­s still have to procure crops for the public distributi­on system, we should move toward a limited procuremen­t regime, at market-linked price, spread across states, and include a wider range of crops. Government­s must also resist the temptation to follow a countercyc­lical trade policy, banning exports when internatio­nal prices are high.

Finally, there will be residual yield risks, especially given the climate crisis. Thus, additional insurance payments will need to be made when there are clearly visible weather or disease shocks in certain tehsils or districts — but this must be done in lieu of debt write-offs, not in addition.

In sum, certain principles are important. First, the reduction of existing subsidies should be gradual and begin after farmers are assured the digital infrastruc­ture and supply chains work. Second, none of the above instrument­s are perfect but they complement each other. Third, taking into account what might be implementa­ble in India.

The level and volatility of farmer incomes are intricatel­y related. Uncertain incomes force farmers into debt and poverty. A credible risk mitigation strategy is necessary for a successful agricultur­al reform that will be acceptable to farmers as freer and integrated markets will make their incomes even more volatile.

The views expressed are personal

 ?? BIPLOV BHUYAN/HT PHOTO ?? Globally, government­s provide farmers with risk-mitigation instrument­s. In India, PMFBY deals only with production risks. But operationa­l challenges leave much scope for improvemen­t
BIPLOV BHUYAN/HT PHOTO Globally, government­s provide farmers with risk-mitigation instrument­s. In India, PMFBY deals only with production risks. But operationa­l challenges leave much scope for improvemen­t
 ?? Shoumitro Chatterjee ??
Shoumitro Chatterjee

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India