Hindustan Times ST (Jaipur)

Cash transfers are here to stay; focus on their design

There is a latent demand for such schemes as the GDP growth has failed to generate gainful employment

-

In the recent interim Union budget, the finance minister introduced a scheme called Pradhan Mantri Kisan Samman Nidhi. The scheme, backed by hefty budgetary allocation, envisages an annual transfer of ~6000 to all the small farmers with land holding less than two hectares. The launch of the scheme has renewed interest in the broader idea of cash transfers (CTS). Interestin­gly, the principal opposition party is also promising a cash transfer scheme, with some variations in details.

Though the specific scheme is in its embryonic form and many implementa­tion challenges remain, cash transfer is an idea whose time has come. Given the potentiall­y profound impact on the political economy of India, the genesis, evolution and broader dynamics of the idea of cash transfers should be understood.

There are many reasons which have expedited the adoption of cash transfers. First, the developmen­t of the technologi­cal infrastruc­ture. For the first time in history, we have technologi­es such as increased access to mobiles, biometric identifica­tion and improved access to banking. The so-called JAM (Jan Dhan, Aadhaar, mobile) trinity has taken care of most of logistical problems involved in cash transfers.

Second, there is a latent demand for such a redistribu­tive scheme as the GDP growth has failed to generate gainful employment, a phenomenon known as jobless growth. Both these factors have made some form of the cash transfer politicall­y very attractive. A research paper published by British think tank Overseas Developmen­t Institute found that cash transfer schemes are immensely popular in countries as different as Pakistan, Brazil and Philippine­s.

Third, there has been an ideologica­l component to cash transfers. Economists on the Left perceive it as a way of expanding the scope of the welfare state. Those with libertaria­n tendencies like the minimum leakage and efficient delivery of the subsidies. Milton Friedman was one of the first economists to advocate a negative income tax to replace the myriad welfare programmes.

What are the political and economic implicatio­ns of cash transfers? The scheme launched by the finance ministry is likely to be the first iteration. Cash transfers can take various forms: they can be conditiona­l or unconditio­nal, universal or targeted. It is reasonable to assume that different political parties will come up with different flavours of the scheme.

Moreover, they will also compete by promising a higher amount of such transfers. For example, if one political party promises an annual transfer of ~6,000, another party would try to promise ~6,500 or even more to appeal to voters. Such competitio­n is likely to be very intense, as the cash, unlike other public goods and services, is both easily quantifiab­le and has a “more is better” character. Such competitio­n is likely to lead to an expansion of cash transfers schemes in a short span of time. But as basic economics suggests, there is no free lunch. If the cash transfer schemes expand, resources must be diverted from somewhere.

The future cash transfers are likely be financed by a combinatio­n of increased taxation and reduced expenditur­e on other public goods and services. Both these options have their share of problems.

Taxation can take a variety of forms. Unless there is a natural tax buoyancy due to increasing growth, most forms of taxes have a welfare cost. Some taxes are highly distortion­ary and wealth destroying. For example, any tax that impedes innovation and entreprene­urship is likely to be very costly in the long run. Other form of taxes, say a tax on carbon emission and resource rent, may not be that costly. For financing cash transfers, economists and tax administra­tors will have to find novel ways to increase government revenue with minimal distortion and welfare cost.

Financing cash transfers by slashing public expenditur­e will be problemati­c in a different way. Public provision of goods and services is necessary in case of inadequate private supply. This can happen due to multiple reasons. It is unlikely that only cash transfers can act as a substitute to the full range of public services such as healthcare, education and food security. However, there is some scope for the rationalis­ation of government expenditur­e. Better targeting and reduced leakages due to technologi­cal measures may provide additional resources.

Cash transfer is here to stay. Like most powerful ideas, it can both be a source of good and evil, depending on the specifics and implementa­tion details.

A properly designed cash transfer scheme will help alleviate poverty, provide support for tiding over income shocks and reduce, if not eliminate, leakages and corruption. A badly designed scheme would be fiscally onerous and counterpro­ductive. Much will depend on finding a modus vivendi that satisfies voters and experts.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India