Hindustan Times (Noida)

The welfare debate must diversify

Focussing primarily on corruption is not the only way out of India’s broken welfare system

- YAMINI AIYAR

The twin announceme­nts of the launch of the PM-KISAN programme in the 2019 budget and the Congress Party’s promise of a minimum income guarantee if elected to power have reignited an important debate on the feasibilit­y of a basic income transfer in India. India’s corrupt, inefficien­t and broken welfare state lies at the heart of this debate. Part of the appeal of a basic income, universal or otherwise, lies in its perceived potential of bypassing and possibly fixing this broken welfare state. In making the case for a Universal Basic Income (UBI), the 2017 economic survey argued that by moving resources directly to beneficiar­y accounts, income transfers have the potential of cutting down bureaucrat­ic layers. This could curb discretion, simplify monitoring and, therefore, reduce corruption.

The merits of this argument aside, the contours of the debate on income transfers and state capacity raise a fundamenta­l concern about how the challenge of India’s broken welfare state is being understood and addressed. The core question this debate provokes is: Has the focus on corruption and inefficien­cy set limits on our understand­ing of how the welfare state functions? Consequent­ly, do current prescripti­ons like income transfers run the risk of reinforcin­g rather than resolving the problem?

Perhaps the best illustrati­on of this concern is in the experience of the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (MGNREGS), a programme that is emblematic of the very failures that the income transfers, in principal, seek to resolve. But experience with addressing corruption in MGNREGS holds important lessons both for the potential of income transfers and the larger concern of fixing India’s broken welfare state. The concern with corruption was paramount when MGNRERGS was designed and in response a number of transparen­cy requiremen­ts were built into it. Over the years, innovation­s were introduced, particular­ly through the use of technology, to streamline administra­tion and curb corruption. Evidence on the effects of these measures highlight important, unexpected effects that, ironically, served to undermine the very objective of curbing corruption — ensuring that beneficiar­ies received work and appropriat­e wages.

An experiment­al study in Bihar, by economist Abhijit Banerjee and others, focused on the corruption effects of a technology-based reform to streamline the administra­tion of fund transfers by reducing administra­tive layers. The study found definitive evidence of reduced corruption but there was little increase in employment or wages. This resonates with an ethnograph­ic study on the effects of transparen­cy requiremen­ts in MGNERGS in Uttrakhand by Nayanika Mathur. Increased transparen­cy curbed corruption by preventing bureaucrat­s from striking deals with contractor­s, as was the norm. But paradoxica­lly, implementa­tion suffered. While the old system broke down, Mathur argues that transparen­cy placed laborious paperwork demands on officers leaving them with little time to build capacities for the new model of implementa­tion. Economist Martin Ravallion offers a more provocativ­e explanatio­n for implementa­tion failure — tighter scrutiny significan­tly increased the costs of corruption because siphoning funds now required the cooperatio­n of a larger network of officers along the delivery chain. When money couldn’t be made and workloads increased, the incentives to implement the scheme to the letter reduced resulting in slow/ no implementa­tion.

This is not to suggest that transparen­cy and administra­tive simplifica­tion is not necessary, rather to point out that transparen­cy without deeper reforms — enhancing human resources, technical skills and crucially building citizen awareness—the positive effects of transparen­cy goals are undermined. Ironically, the focus on corruption detracted from efforts to strengthen capacities of local administra­tors and Panchayats to deliver the scheme well. Employment suffered but absent strong Panchayats, the quality of infrastruc­ture built has been patchy thus underminin­g the scheme’s welfare impact.

It can be argued that by cutting out the work requiremen­t, the income transfer model could potentiall­y reap the anti-corruption benefits of transparen­cy and administra­tive simplifica­tion in ways that MGNREGS could not. But the reality of implementi­ng income transfers complicate­s this argument. As a recent Niti Aayog study by economist Karthik Muralidhar­an and co-authors on the transition from PDS to cash highlights, getting the cash architectu­re requires significan­t administra­tive interventi­on. From raising beneficiar­y awareness, to building databases, facilitati­ng bank transactio­ns and most crucially tackling citizen disputes, local officials are critical to the success of income transfers. Importantl­y, the current model of targeted transfers that are being proposed, place a significan­t burden of beneficiar­y identifica­tion on the local administra­tion. Absent efforts to strengthen the local welfare state, the increased workload, could well create implementa­tion failure similar to MGNREGS.

But perhaps the most damaging consequenc­e of the focus on corruption is that it has legitimise­d the view that the only way to fix India’s broken welfare state is by curbing discretion and tightening scrutiny. This has served to deeply centralise the welfare bureaucrac­y at the cost of building a local government system that is genuinely responsive to citizen needs. The debate on fixing India’s corrupt welfare bureaucrac­y with or without income transfers misses this crucial reality.

 ?? DIWAKAR PRASAD/HT ?? Local officials are critical to the success of income transfer schemes
DIWAKAR PRASAD/HT Local officials are critical to the success of income transfer schemes
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India