Millennium Post

Finding the right answer

Examining the possibilit­y of using New Institutio­nal Economics in the field of education

- The writer is an IAS officer, working as Principal Resident Commission­er, Government of West Bengal. Views expressed are strictly personal

Universali­sation of primary education is a widely accepted objective of government­s all over the world, particular­ly in developing countries and less developed countries (LDCS). “Education for all” was also accepted as an objective in the UNESCO sponsored Dakar Framework in the year 2000. Education was also a part of Millennium Developmen­t Goals and is an important component of the Sustainabl­e Developmen­t Goals (SDG) being pursued by the UN currently. In particular, the SDG4 aims to ensure inclusive and equitable quality education and learning opportunit­ies for all. The Indian Constituti­on (Directive Principles of State Policy, Article 45) also requires the State to provide free and compulsory education for all children until they complete 14 years.

Education and Economic Theory

In economic theory, education has been dealt with as human capital by Adam Smith as far back as 1776. In trying to explain the cause of the prosperity of nations, he isolated two factors: one, the importance of economies of scale and two, the importance of skill formation and human qualities. The second factor is popular today as ‘human capital’. Thus, it is the comparativ­e advantage in human skills, which gives nations an edge while trading with others, rather than just a difference in physical endowments and the number of factors of production. The latter interpreta­tion of gains from trade is the one given by economists of the classical tradition such as Ricardo. The classical tradition has been long debunked by recent trade and growth theorists, who have emphasised scale advantages and gains from specialisa­tion (Solow 1957; Krugman 1987; Lucas 1988), much as Smith had done two centuries back. The neoclassic­al model specified by Solow (1956) found a large ‘residual’ in explaining economic growth. Later work by Solow (1957) himself and other growth theorists (Romer 1986; Krugman 1987) attributed this ‘residual’ to school education and human capital. This crucial link between human capital and economic progress implies that we should look at the role of public policy in expanding education and promotion of skill formation.

In the neoclassic­al tradition, another important approach to education was put forward by Gary Becker in 1964. Proposing the ‘Human Capital Theory’, Becker regarded education as an investment that conferred benefits at the individual level as well as the collective level. However, since the individual­istic perspectiv­e prevails in neoclassic­al economics, the collective aspects of education got pushed to the background. Another neoclassic­al interpreta­tion of education is based on the characteri­stic of a public good, viz., non-rivalrous (one person’s consumptio­n does not reduce the other person’s consumptio­n) and non-excludabil­ity (one cannot exclude anyone from consuming a good once it has been produced). The logic here is that the public good supply such as that of education is plagued by the free-riding problem, which justifies the state provision of the good. The common thread in most neoclassic­al narratives is that education supply is characteri­sed by market failure due to the free-riding problem and therefore is a fit case for being provided by the state.

The view of education as a public good has been challenged in recent times for various reasons. One reason is that it is neither non-rivalrous (increasing class size does reduce the other person’s consumptio­n) nor non-excludable (anyone can be excluded from consumptio­n by imposing fee barriers). Another reason is that state provision of education, particular­ly primary and secondary education has not given desirable results. That this has been the case in both developed countries such as the United States and in most developing countries particular­ly in South Asia and Sub-saharan Africa tells us that the level of developmen­t does not seem to be causing this dismal state of affairs. Typically, problems such as teacher absenteeis­m, low quality of teaching, poor learning outcomes and higher rates of dropouts are noticed in both developed and developing countries. Another problem in many developing countries is that the poor have to depend only on state-provided primary and secondary education since there are either no private sector schools available or are beyond the paying capacity of the poor. This gives the public sector a monopoly position leading to inadequate provision of education.

As an alternativ­e to education as a public good, Musgrave in 1959 introduced the concept of merit goods and suggested that primary and secondary education be considered as such merit goods. The rational suggested by Musgrave was education services ought to be subsidised because of social and ethical reasons and the positive externalit­ies that it provides.

Another reason why the idea of education as a public good is coming into question is because of the emergence of private players in the supply of primary and secondary education all over the world. Not only that, it appears that the public sector is also receding from the stage because of budgetary constraint­s. To take the example of India, the public expenditur­e on education (both at the central and state levels) has remained at 3 per cent of GDP at least for the last few decades.

An interestin­g developmen­t has been the use of vouchers in the supply of primary and secondary education. Vouchers are basically certificat­es provided to parents, which can be used to fund their children’s education. Vouchers give more freedom to parents to choose a school of their choice. The school chosen can be a public or private school. The rationale of the school voucher system is that it provides a healthy competitio­n among suppliers of education services, thereby leading to the most optimal quality of education at the best prices. In addition, the voucher system provides consumer choice. While vouchers have been popular in the United

States, the Europeans have opted for a subsidised system of school education. In India, the Delhi Voucher Project was launched in 2007 where schools vouchers worth up to Rs 3,600 per year were given to students for a minimum of 3 years. The voucher system does not seem to have taken off in India. This is perhaps because of the Right to Education Act which was passed in 2009 which makes education a fundamenta­l right of every child.

Education in an NIE framework

In a report by NITI Aayog of November 2018 titled Strategy for New India, the issue of education has been discussed in some detail. The report highlights the following challenges: Poor learning outcomes; poor Governance and inadequate monitoring of schools; lack of teacher training and falling enrolment in government schools and rising enrolment in private schools.

We may recall that NIE basically attempts to incorporat­e a theory of institutio­ns into economics. This is different from the traditiona­l neoclassic­al world, where there are no institutio­ns, there is perfect and complete informatio­n, zero transactio­n costs and decision-makers are perfectly rational with unlimited computatio­n powers. Hence, the important elements of NIE are asymmetric and incomplete informatio­n, challenges with respect to enforcemen­t of contracts, limited mental capacity, high level of transactio­n costs and bounded rationalit­y. In such a world, institutio­ns become important and provide certainty in various exchanges, production processes and performanc­e of the economy. We may recall that Ronald Coase in his essay in 1960, Problem of Social Cost had theorised that markets are not efficient because it is costly to transact and to overcome these transactio­ns costs, institutio­ns are important. Embedded in the NIE framework is the principal-agent problem which arises as a result of asymmetric informatio­n and incomplete informatio­n referred to above.

Applying the above framework to primary and secondary education settings, we see that there are a number of principal-agent dyads in the school education system such as parents – teachers, headmaster – teachers, government – teachers. The basic problem is that the government, through its education bureaucrac­y is unable to monitor behaviour, performanc­e and output of the teachers.

The Way out

While school education in developing countries has witnessed great progress in terms of almost universal enrolment and better infrastruc­ture (more classrooms, better teaching aids etc.), challenges of quality of outcomes remain. In India, various Education Commission­s and National Policies, coupled with programs such as District Primary Education Program (DPEP) and Sarva Shiksha Abhiyan (SSA) have shown sterling results in terms of universal enrolment and better infrastruc­ture. However, as noted by the NITI Aayog report above, challenges on quality remain.

The way out is provided from NIE above: ‘Institutio­ns’ need to be strengthen­ed in the following manner: The compulsory formation of Parent-teacher Associatio­ns (PTAS); the District Inspectora­te of Schools needs to be strengthen­ed and made more accountabl­e so that periodic inspection­s are made compulsory; these inspection­s must improve teachers’ attendance and the quality of teaching; increasing teacher training and making it more contextual and effective and exploring school vouchers in those areas where private schools have come up in substantia­l numbers.

Evidence of the efficacy of the above institutio­nal interventi­ons was found in a study undertaken by this author when he was District Magistrate, Nadia in West Bengal (in 2003-04). In a program titled ‘School Sampark Abhiyan’, 927 schools were visited by all officials of the State Government and Panchayat bodies (including the author) and a questionna­ire designed by the author was filled out to make a database of basic variables such as teacher’s attendance, infrastruc­ture of schools, teachers’ training, inspection by the District Inspectora­te and learning achievemen­t. It was found that most of the variables, which we have referred to as ‘Institutio­ns’ above, have a positive impact on learning outcomes. In short, institutio­ns matter!

The view of education as a public good has been challenged in recent times for various reasons. One reason is that it is neither nonrivalro­us nor non-excludable (anyone can be excluded from consumptio­n by imposing fee barriers). Another reason is that state provision of education, particular­ly primary and secondary education has not given desirable results

 ??  ?? For India, the public expenditur­e on education has remained at 3% of GDP at least for the last few decades
For India, the public expenditur­e on education has remained at 3% of GDP at least for the last few decades
 ??  ?? KRISHNA GUPTA
KRISHNA GUPTA

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India